During the years covered in this volume,
Europe experienced a tumultuous period of civil wars and rebellions. The common
thread running through the upheavals was strife between adherents of the
Catholic and Protestant churches. But in this new edition Richard S. Dunn shows
that there were more lasting developments in European history that can be
traced to this period. It was an age that witnessed new centralization of
political and economic power in the state—the rise of absolutism and the spread
of the mercantilist doctrine. And it was a golden age of intellectual
achievement climaxed by a great scientific revolution and a burst of creativity
in the arts and literature.
By Richard S. Dunn
Professor of history at
the University of Pennsylvania.
Introduction
Symbol of a new era—the Protestant Archbishop Cranmer burned at the
stake in 1556 by the Catholic Queen Mary of England. This woodcut is from John Foxe’s Book of Martyrs (1563), the most popular English book—next to the
Bible—for a century, and the Protestant counterpart to a Catholic Lives
of the Saints.
DURING the century and a half between 1559 and 1715, Europe was in a nearly
constant state of war. There were fewer than thirty years of international
peace, and more than a hundred years of major combat, in which all or most of
the leading European states were simultaneously engaged. Warfare has of course
been endemic throughout European history, but the fighting in these years had
its distinctive features. For nearly a century, from 1559 to 1648, the common
denominator was Protestant-Catholic religious strife. This confessional
conflict was passionate and highly disruptive. After the mid-seventeenth
century, combat reverted to a more secular and orderly pattern. Thus our period
marks the apogee and the decline of religious warfare in Europe.
The battles fought between Protestants and
Catholics in the late sixteenth and early seventeenth centuries were
tumultuous and anarchic because they characteristically took the form of civil
war and rebellion. Luther had inaugurated the ideological controversy in 1517,
but Luther was not a political activist. Confessional conflict intensified in
the mid sixteenth century when a new breed of militant Protestant and Catholic
champions came to the fore. The French civil wars of 1562-1598, the Dutch
revolt against Philip II, the Scottish rebellion against Mary Stuart, the
Spanish attack on England in 1588, the Thirty Years’ War in Germany between
1618 and 1648, and the Puritan Revolution of 1640-1660 and the Glorious Revolution of
1688-1689 in England were all religious conflicts, though of course they had
other causes as well. This was an age of crusaders and martyrs, of plots and
assassinations, of fanatic mobs and psalm-singing armies. The most
militant crusaders proved to be the disciples of John Calvin and of St.
Ignatius of Loyola. The Calvinists gained control of Scotland and the Dutch
republic, temporarily seized power in England, and tried to take over in
France, Germany, Poland, and Hungary. The Catholics, revitalized in the
mid-sixteenth century, kept trying until the late seventeenth century to
restore the seamless unity of the Christian Church. In France, Flanders,
Austria, and Bohemia, at least, they successfully suppressed Protestantism. Both
sides in this extraordinary contest were able to attract a high percentage of
articulate, prosperous, and socially powerful people into their ranks. Both
sides gradually lost their crusading zeal.
After 1648, and particularly after 1689,
religion was no longer the common denominator—though it remained a disruptive
factor—in European international conflict. The great wars that wracked western
Europe from 1688 to 1713 and eastern Europe from 1683 to 1721 were larger in
scale than the earlier civil wars and rebellions, but they were far less
alarming to the established order, because they were managed from above by
kings and generals rather than plotted from below by rebels and crusaders. The
effect of these wars at the close of our period was to repudiate the confessional
turmoil of 1559-1648 and to restore a more stable balance of power among the
chief European states.
Such is the bald outline of the story that
follows. But there is far more to it. The period from 1559 to 1715 is
remembered for a wide array of political, economic, social, and intellectual
developments, subject to sharply conflicting interpretations. Some historians
label this period the age of absolutism; some call it the age of mercantilism;
others focus on the growth of bourgeois enterprise or the rise of
constitutional, representative government. For government, For intellectual
historians, this is preeminently a time of scientific revolution; for art
historians it is the era of the Baroque; for literary historians, the golden
age of the drama. Social historians, on the other hand, are inclined to find
the years between the Reformation and the Enlightenment a dark time of famine,
plague, poverty, slavery, and belief in witchcraft. The diversity of opinion
recalls the story of the blind men who encountered an elephant and disagreed
about what they had found. But the analogy is faulty, for those who study early
modern Europe are neither blind nor wrongheaded. Interpretations are
necessarily diverse because sixteenth- and seventeenth-century developments
were so richly complex. To make sense out of the events between 1559 and 1715,
we must observe the continuous interaction between contradictory forces:
confessional strife, political absolutism, bourgeois enterprise, mercantilist
regulation, peasant malaise, cultural innovation, and social repression. We can
then appreciate the way in which the age of religious wars left a permanent
impress upon nearly every aspect of European life: on concepts of liberty and
toleration, on party politics, the art of kingship, business enterprise, the
social structure, science, philosophy, and the arts.
EUROPE IN 1559
What were the most distinctive features of
European society in the mid-sixteenth century?
Examination of the map of Europe in 1559
shows a state system that looks partly familiar and partly strange to the
modern eye. Politically, Europe was divided into three zones—western, central,
and eastern—and this division remained a basic fact of political life for the
next century or more. The section of the map showing the eastern zone, where
the Ottoman Empire, Poland-Lithuania, and Muscovite Russia were the chief
states, looks unfamiliar because the Polish-Russian border stood much farther
eastward than it does today and the Ottoman Empire embraced all of the Balkans.
The Ottoman Turks and the Muscovites were isolated from the rest of Europe by
religion and culture, and the whole eastern region was hobbled by a primitive
economy, thinly dispersed population, loose political organization (except for
the Ottomans), and deep internal ethnic divisions. In the central zone, by
contrast, the Italians and Germans had long been the business and cultural
leaders of Europe. But events in the early sixteenth century had devastated the
central European political structure. The Italian state system had been wrecked
by French, Spanish, and German invaders between the 1490’s and the 1520’s, and
the Holy Roman Empire had been paralyzed by civil war, lasting from 1520 In
1555 and unresolved by the Augsburg peace settlement of 1 555. The section of
the map showing central Europe in 1559 looks especially sli.mp because the Holy
Roman Empire incorporated what is now West and East Germany, Switzerland,
Austria, and much of Czechoslovakia, Poland and Italy, as well as the Low Countries
in the western zone. This empire was not a cohesive state; it consisted of
three hundred separate political units, none of them very large, joined bv a
system of alliances. Thus central Europe was politically particularistic and
divided. In the western zone, however, the leading Atlantic states—Spain,
France, and England—had gained notably in cohesion and power during the
preceding century. The section of the map showing this region appears much as
it does today, except that France’s eastern border is more circumscribed, and
the Netherlands have not yet been divided into modern Holland, Belgium, and
Luxemburg. By 1559 the Atlantic states had developed considerable national
identity; they were political units in which kings had sovereign authority over
extensive, populous territories, with coherent linguistic or ethnic
consciousness.
The significance of this three-zone
division is that the political center of gravity lay in western Europe. Spain
and France were the two most powerful states, by far, in 1559. And during the
ensuing religious wars the English and the Dutch developed new political
effectiveness, while the chief central and eastern empires and kingdoms
remained disorganized and weak. Economically, too, the Atlantic states occupied
the first rank. Their merchants were by far the most successful businessmen of
the day, developing a prosperous and expanding commercial capitalist economy,
while the older trade and industrial centers of Germany and Italy atrophied,
and the agriculture of eastern Europe stagnated. Success in politics and
economics was mirrored in artistic and intellectual expression; here too the
Atlantic peoples became the cultural leaders of Europe. Inevitably, therefore,
our focus must be on western Europe.
Even the most prosperous regions of
western Europe were shackled in 1559 by primitive production techniques. There
was far from enough wealth for all to share. In consequence, society was
everywhere organized along profoundly undemocratic lines. The disparity between
the upper and the lower classes, the propertied and the propertyless, was
tremendous. At the top of the social scale, a small number of aristocratic
landlords monopolized most of the political power, social privileges, and
wealth. At the bottom of the social scale (the submerged six sevenths of the
iceberg, so to speak), millions of peasants eked out a bare subsistence,
excluded from schools, skilled jobs, property ownership, and creature comforts.
Hut this hierarchical system was not immobile. In the populous cities and towns
of western and central Europe, the merchants and lawyers competed with the
landed elite for wealth and position, while the humbler shopkeepers and
artisans scrabbled for smaller stakes. As we shall see in most of the Atlantic
states these urban classes gained appreciably in numbers and strength during
the late sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. In Germany and Italy they lost
ground. In eastern Europe they remained inconsequential. But even in western
Europe the social gulf between an upwardly mobile merchant and an established
landed gentleman was very striking. A gentleman did not work. He had numerous
servants to work for him. He spent his time at play, fighting, or hunting. He
spent his money on ostentatious luxuries. Everything about his life style
differed so radically from that of the lower orders that he seemed to represent
a higher biological species. Since land was everywhere scarce and especially
valuable, the gentleman landowner deliberately squandered part of his acreage
on a deer park and pleasure gardens. And he sustained his privileged status by
bequeathing hereditary titles and possessions to his children.
The hereditary hierarchical principle was
equally conspicuous in politics. Aristocrats almost everywhere dominated the
political scene and passed their power from generation to generation. In every
large state, a divinely ordained prince, king, or emperor presided over the
aristocratic establishment. In three monarchies—the Holy Roman Empire, the
papacy, and Poland—the ruler was elected by lesser princes. Elsewhere, royal
titles were hereditary—a species of property, to be conveyed by the reigning
family from one generation to the next. Obviously this system did not guarantee
continuous talent: a strong king might be succeeded by his strong son, as
happened in Spain in 1556; or an inept queen might be succeeded by her
brilliant sister, as happened in England in 1558; or a mediocre king might be
succeeded by his even feebler son, as happened in France in 1559.
There was also another significant
political tendency, illustrated by the most prominent princely family of the
day, the house of Habsburg. A conspicuous feature of the 1559 map is the
extraordinarily diverse collection of territories governed by the Habsburgs.
Philip II, of the Spanish Habsburgs, was hereditary ruler of twelve separate
European territories, several North African outposts, and a vast New World
empire. His uncle Ferdinand I, of the Austrian Habsburgs, was hereditary ruler
of thirteen territories, besides being the elected Holy Roman emperor. Between
them, Philip and Ferdinand ruled possessions incorporated today into fourteen
European and three North African nations. The Habsburgs were dynastic princes
par excellence; they aimed at family power more than state power, and their
style of rule inhibited national development. Collecting their princely titles
like pearls on a necklace through inheritance, marriage, war, and diplomacy,
they handled each possession independently, mainly through deputies. The other
chief princely families—Valois, Guise, Bourbon, Orange, Tudor, Stuart,
Wittelsbach, Hohenzollern, Vasa, and Romanov—followed the Habsburg model,
pursuing dynastic ambitions and staging dynastic wars that often held no
benefit for the peoples they ruled. In the political system of early modern
Europe, there was constant unresolved tension between state building and family
building.
The old familiar political problems were
compounded by strange new religious problems. In the forty years since Martin
Luther had launched his revolt, the people of western and central Europe had
gradually arrayed themselves into warring Protestant and Catholic camps.
Furthermore, the Protestants were themselves split into rival
denominations—Lutheran, Calvinist, Zwinglian, Anabaptist, and Anglican—which
were bitterly antagonistic toward one another. By 1559 the religious map was
exceedingly confused. The Catholics had firm control of Portugal, Spain, and
Italy; the Protestants had firm control of Scandinavia. Everywhere else, the
struggle continued. The Catholics held the upper hand in France, Ireland, the
Netherlands, southern Germany, Bohemia, Hungary, and Poland, but faced a
powerful Protestant challenge. The Protestants held the upper hand in England,
Scotland, most of Germany, and Switzerland, but faced a powerful Catholic
challenge. Fluid as the situation was, neither Protestants nor Catholics were
in the least willing to compromise—or to coexist. Everyone agreed that
religious toleration was intolerable. Every prince strove for religious
uniformity, and insisted on the right to impose one particular interpretation
of Christian faith upon every subject. But as we shall sec, convinced
Protestants tended to rebel against their Catholic princes, and convinced
Catholics against their Protestant princes.
Nor was this the only new problem. From
the mid-sixteenth century on, most regions of Europe were buffeted by
population pressure, rapid inflation, and eroding living standards for the
laboring poor. Overall, the population had been rising for the past century, so
that by 1559 the catastrophic losses caused by the Black Death two hundred
years earlier had finally been made up. The demographic expansion of 1460-1559
had stimulated agricultural expansion, industrial production, and commerce:
there had been a century of general prosperity. But after 1559, the picture
darkened. Population continued to climb, and with all available land under
cultivation, peasants were forced to work smaller and smaller plots, while the
landless were driven to seek work in the cities and towns. Unemployment
increased, the supply of food fell behind the demand for it, the price of bread
rose faster than the income of wage workers, and beggars proliferated. Those
who lived close to the margin—the vast majority of the population—were terribly
exposed to famine and plague. Famine struck with devastating effect whenever
the harvest failed. The bubonic plague, endemic since the Black Death two
centuries earlier, repeatedly thinned out the crowded urban slums. As we shall
see, it was no accident that the great witchcraft hysteria, one of the most
distinctive phenomena in the age of religious wars, began in the 1560’s. For 1
lie witch-hunters of the late sixteenth century were not merely intensely
religious – preoccupied with heresy and sin, and fascinated by the Devil and by
black magic. They also had a desperate need for scapegoats to meliorate the impact
of social disasters for which they had no remedy: poverty, disease, crime,
famine, plague, wartime carnage, and Revolutionary upheaval, all characteristic
of the troubled society we are about to examine.
One final, ironic point. In a world full
of dispute and uncertainly, there was at least one proposition that every
sixteenth-century male, whether Catholic or Protestant, gentleman or peasant,
could agree upon; this was the fixed inferiority of the female sex. Women were
spiritually frail, physically passive, socially subordinate, economically
dependent. Needless to say, they had no voice in politics. But in 1558-1561
three women assumed great political power. Elizabeth I became queen of England,
Mary Stuart became queen of Scotland, and Catherine dc Medici became queen
mother and effectual ruler of France. John Knox summed up the male reaction in
his famous pamphlet, The First Blast of the Trumpet Against the Monstrous
Regiment of Women (1558). A female ruling over men, said Knox, is
repugnant to nature and contrary to God’s revealed will. In public affairs a
woman’s sight is blindness, her counsel foolishness, and her judgment frenzy.
Despite Knox’s fulminations, the three queens held center stage for the next
thirty years. It was indeed a novel age!
Chapter 1
Calvinism Versus Catholicism
in Western Europe
John Calvin. This woodcut shows the stern reformer
in old age.
St. Ignatius of Loyola. Engraving by Vosterman.
This portrait romanticizes Loyola somewhat, but catches his psychological
intensity and robust zed.
Philip II. Painting by Coello. The king, true to
his character, looks gravely dignified and is austerely dressed in black. Museo
del Prado, Madrid.
The Escorial. Painting by an unknown artist. The
isolated setting, huge bulk, gridiron design, and monastic severity of Philip
II’s retreat are dearly shown. Standing in the center of the complex is the
domed church.
The St. Bartholomew Massacre. By Francois Dubois
d’Amiens. This gory Parisian panorama shows the Catholics pushing Coligny out
a window and then (in the street below) flaying his corpse, while Guise
displays the admiral’s severed head. Catherine de Medici inspects a pile of
bodies. Other Huguenot victims are seen gibbeted, stabbed, clubbed, or floating
in the Seine, while their more fortunate colleagues escape the city through a
gate on the left bank. Museum Arland, Geneva.
The assassination of Henry, duke
of Guise, in 1588. The pro-Guise artist shows the assassins drawing their
weapons as they converge on the unsuspecting duke, stab him, and drag his body
behind a tapestry as Henry III looks on.
The sea beggars capture Brielle, 1 572. This was the first coastal town taken by the Dutch rebels, who are
shown using artillery, musketeers, and pikemen to break in at the town gate.
The Ditchley portrait of Elizabeth I. The queen is shown as she liked to be portrayed, in fantastic costume,
standing on a map of her beloved England, impervious to thunderstorms.
National Portrait Gallery, London.
The execution of Mary, Queen of Scots. This contemporary drawing shows (upper left) the queen entering the
great hall of Fotheringhay Castle, and then (center) standing on the execution
platform by the chopping block, attended by her ladies and watched by guards
and neighborhood gentry.
The defeat of the Spanish Armada. An
old English print showing the crescentshaped Spanish fleet in flight and one
struggling Spanish ship (lower left) being hunted down. The English ships
display the red cross of St. George on their ensigns. The Spanish oared galley
(lower right) was better suited to the Mediterranean than the Atlantic.
The Surrender of Breda. This
famous painting by Velazquez celebrates one of Spain’s few seventeenth-century
victories. In 1625, after an eight-month siege, a Spanish army took the Dutch
frontier town of Breda. In 1637, shortly after Velazquez commemorated this
triumph, the Dutch recaptured Breda. Museo del Prado, Barcelona.
In the spring of 1559, envoys from Philip II of Spain and Henry II of France met on
neutral ground in the bishop’s palace at Cateau-Cambresis, a little town on the
French-Netherlands border, to arrange a peace treaty between their respective
masters. Philip and Henry were the two strongest princes in Europe, but they
both needed peace. Their rival dynastic houses, the Habsburgs and the Valois, had
been dueling inconclusively for half a century, and their treasuries were
exhausted. Furthermore, the Catholic King of Spain and the Most Christian King
of France had a common enemy to deal with. The Protestant heresy was spreading
from central Europe into Spanish and French territory, and Philip and Henry
were determined to stamp it out. Accordingly, the diplomats at Cateau-Cambresis
worked out a peace settlement which could be expected to last for many years.
The French abandoned their efforts to wrest Italy and the Low Countries from
Spain; the Spaniards abandoned their efforts to dismember France. The Peace of
Cateau-Cambresis was more a Habsburg than a Valois victory, since France
remained encircled by Habsburg territory. But Valois France in 1559 was rich,
populous, and powerful. Surely this settlement was mutually advantageous to
Philip and Henry. The reconciled Habsburg and Valois monarchs would now be able
to crush Protestantism within their territories and join forces to restore the
seamless unity of the Christian Church.
But to their surprise and dismay, the
Peace of Cateau-Cambresis ushered in a strange new era of civil wars and
rebellions which the Habsburg and Valois kings were quite unable to cope with.
The religious conflict which had racked central Europe from 1517 to 1555 moved
with a new revolutionary force into western Europe between 1560 and 1600. In
Germany the fighting had come to a temporary halt. The truce between the
Protestants and the Catholics in the Holy Roman Empire, established in 1555 by
the Peace of Augsburg, lasted into the early seventeenth century. But in
western Europe, Dutch Calvinists rebelled against Spanish Habsburg control of
the Netherlands, while French Calvinists, or Huguenots, rebelled against the
Valois monarchy and plunged France into forty years of civil war. At the same
time in England and Scotland, Calvinists, Catholics, and Anglicans were vying
for political mastery. In essence, western Europe became a giant battleground
fought over by two crusading armies, Calvinist and Catholic.
The Calvinists employed the dogma and
discipline of Geneva to challenge the political status quo in France,
the Low Countries, and the British Isles. They proved to be effective rebels,
for though few in number, they were drawn .chiefly from the upper and middle
classes, and were zealous and self-assured. The Catholics, led by Philip II,
employed all the resources of the mighty Spanish empire to crush the’ French
Huguenots and restore Britain and the Netherlands to Rome. Calvinists and
Catholics alike can be labeled “conservative” in the sense that they clung to
the traditional medieval belief that no diversity could be tolerated within
Christendom. There was just one interpretation of God’s commands, just one road
to salvation; only by vanquishing the forces of Satan could Christ’s rule on
earth be achieved. Yet what gave the Calvinists and Catholics such dynamic
power was their active involvement in the world. Both sides recognized the new
secular forces which were transforming western civilization—overseas expansion
to Asia and America, commercial capitalism, dynastic rivalry, nationalism, and
state sovereignty—and they harnessed these forces to the service of God. The
Calvinist-Catholic struggle was in one sense the last medieval crusade, in
another the first modern war between nation-states. Nothing like it has ever
been seen before or since.
From the day Martin Luther first posted
his ninety-five theses in 1517, the religious controversy between Protestants
and Catholics was embroiled in politics. This was inevitable. The spiritual
crisis affected men’s attitudes toward this world as well as the next. The
Church possessed vast political and economic resources, and when the
Protestants repudiated the basic doctrinal tenets of Rome, they necessarily
also attacked the Church’s existing institutional fabric. Protestant and
Catholic reformers alike looked to the secular authorities for help, and kings
and princes gained political and economic advantage from participating in the
conflict.
At mid-century, subtle—but
crucial—religious and political changes took place. With the death of John
Calvin in 1564, the initial creative work of the Protestant reformers was
completed. Correspondingly, with the death of St. Ignatius of Loyola in 1556,
and the termination of the Council of Trent in 1563, the Catholic internal
reform program was fully spelled out. The ideological battle lines became
frozen. But as the Protestants and Catholics lost their initial spiritual
creativity, they developed a new political creativity.
The Protestants and
Catholics of the late sixteenth century quarreled over predetermined issues.
The central spiritual and intellectual questions had all been explored,
debated, and formulated between 1517 and 1564. No Protestant theologian
remotely comparable to Luther, Zwingli, or Calvin emoted during the second half
of the century. The Protestants had long since fragmented into a spectrum of
mutually jealous churches and sects, each with its well-defined doctrinal,
ritualistic, and institutional idiosyncrasies. ()n the Catholic side, the
cumulative effect of the internal reform program launched in the 1 530’s had
been to stiffen resistance to all major Protestant tenets. The Council of Trent
had declared that every existing Catholic ritual or practice was spiritually
efficacious. Far from decentralizing the Church, the Trentine reforms magnified
the hierarchical authority of pope, cardinals, and bishops. The Jesuits, most
effective of the new reforming orders, took a special vow of obedience to the
pope. The Roman Inquisition and the Index of Prohibited Books helped to protect
the faithful from Protestant propaganda, just as the Consistory in Geneva
shielded orthodox Calvinists from wicked external influences. After 1560,
Protestants and Catholics had no interest in spiritual or intellectual
reconciliation, and had nothing fresh to say to each other. Each side sought to
convert the other by sheer brute force.
If the religious dimension
of the quarrel became frozen, the political dimension was in a state of flux.
In the early days, particularly between the 1520’s and the 1550’s, the kings
and princes of central and western Europe had been able to shape and
stage-manage the Protestant-Catholic conflict to a very great degree. The
German princes who protected Luther from the pope and the emperor had embraced
the new religion with possessive enthusiasm. The national Protestant churches
of Sweden, Denmark, and England, established in the 1520’s and 1530’s, had all
been founded by kings who eagerly assumed most of the perquisites they stripped
from the pope. “The Reformation maintained itself wherever the lay power
(prince or magistrates) favoured it; it could not survive where the authorities
decided to suppress it.” Even the Catholic rulers had profited from
the crisis up to the mid-sixteenth century. The German Catholic princes, the
Habsburgs in Spain, and the Valois in France all had exacted papal concessions
which tightened their hold over their territorial churches. They were very
suspicious of any revival of papal power. Charles V’s soldiers sacked Rome,
not Wittenberg, in 1527, and when the papacy belatedly sponsored a reform
program, both the Habsburgs and the Valois refused to endorse much of it, rejecting
especially, those Trentine decrees which encroached on their sovereign
authority. In refusing to cooperate with Rome, the Catholic princes checked
papal ambitions to restore the Church’s medieval political power. By
patronizing the Protestant reformers, the Protestant princes made sure that
their reforms did not go too far.
After 1560 the rulers of western Europe
were no longer able to blunt the revolutionary force of the religious crisis.
Both Calvinists and militant Catholics began to rebel against the political status
quo. They organized effective opposition against rulers who did not share
their religious convictions. In the name of God they launched a wave of civil
wars and rebellions against constituted authority. Mary, Queen of Scots, lost
her throne and her life. Catherine de Medici of France got caught between
Huguenot and ultra-Catholic crusaders. Under her management, the Valois dynasty
collapsed and the French central government crumbled. Philip II of Spain was a
far more heroic figure than Mary or Catherine, and was the prime champion of
the Church among sixteenth-century princes. His motives were mixed, for he
hoped to extend his dynastic power by crushing the heretics, but at the same
time, no other political leader risked so much for his faith. He risked too
much, as events proved, and instead of gaining territory, he lost some. He
provoked a Calvinist rebellion in the Netherlands which could not be
suppressed; his intervention in the French religious wars backfired; and he
failed to conquer Protestant England. It is instructive that the two western
European rulers who best survived the religious crisis behaved much more
circumspectly than Philip. Both Elizabeth I of England and Henry IV of France
pursued policies of moderation and compromise which eventually disarmed their
Calvinist and Catholic critics. But even Elizabeth and Henry were thrown on the
defensive most of the time.
The Calvinists, who caused
so much trouble to these princes, were never very numerous. Calvin himself had
had a restricted base of operations: his little city-state of Geneva on the
French border of Switzerland had only thirteen thousand inhabitants. But
Calvin’s teachings and his Presbyterian church structure proved to be highly
exportable to larger centers of population and power. Before lie died in 1564,
he had gained an elite following in France, the Netherlands, Scotland, and
England. The movement attracted recruits from the privileged classes: noblemen,
landowners, merchants, and lawyers. Persons from the unprivileged classes,
peasants and urban wage laborers, were less likely to join. Today Calvinism has
the reputation of being a misanthropic, repressive creed. How could it win such
aristocratic and prosperous adherents, let alone fire up a crusade? The best
answer, perhaps, is that it offered a harsh but immensely exhilarating
challenge. One had to accept Calvin’s concept of God’s absolute and
all-pervading power and of Man’s utter depravity, which renders him incapable
of fulfilling God’s law as revealed in the Bible. One had also to believe that
God chooses to save some few persons, not on their merits (they have none), but
solely by His grace. The person who accepted these premises, who abased himself
before God’s will and experienced God’s irresistible grace, knew that he was
among the predestinated “elect” or “saints,” the only true Christians. As
Calvin himself explained, “when that light of divine providence has once shone
upon a godly man, he is then relieved and set free not only from the extreme anxiety
and fear that were pressing him before, but from every care.”2
Despite Calvin’s stress on human worthlessness, his church was an exclusive
brotherhood which separated the saints from the sinners, the wheat from the
chaff. Far from being fatalistic, the saints were intensely active.
It has been recently argued
that the sixteenth-century Calvinists organized themselves into the first
modern radical political party, analogous to the Jacobins and the Bolsheviks in
more recent revolutionary times.3 Of course, their chief goal was to
reach the next world, not to remake this one. Yet the saints felt stifled by
their unregenerate neighbors, and supposed that God wished them to master and
reconstruct their corrupt environment. Their fellowship was bound to be socially
and politically disruptive, for Calvinism was a total way of life. Their social
model was Geneva: a homogeneous little city, rigidly self-disciplined,
zealously self-righteous, and independent of any external authority. When
Calvin’s disciples began proselytizing in large and complex states like France,
the Netherlands, and England, they gathered the saints into communities of
Genevan purity and Genevan self-sufficiency. In France, for example, the
Huguenots established congregations on the Gene van model, with pastors who
preached and administered the Lord’s Supper, teachers who educated the young,
deacons who looked after the poor and unemployed, and ciders who watched for
immorality and disorder. The Huguenots united these congregations under a countrywide
discipline, with local consistories and a national synod of the chief clergy
and laymen. Every member of a Calvinist congregation swore to obey and help
enforce God’s law, and this covenant, or contract, to which all agreed, easily
came to serve as a kind of constitution binding the Calvinists in a political
or military confederation against their worldly enemies. Armed with the Genevan
virtues of asceticism, industry, practical education, and moral responsibility,
these people were hard to suppress or silence.
Calvin himself always preached obedience
to the Christian prince. But in 1558, as we have seen in the Introduction, John
Knox (1505-1572), the leading Scottish Calvinist, denounced female rulers in
his First Blast of the Trumpet. Elizabeth I took great offense at this
pamphlet, and was not mollified when Knox lamely explained to her that he
objected only to Catholic queens. By the 1570’s the Huguenots in France had
moved well beyond Knox’s position, and were arguing that resistance to tyrants,
male or female, was divinely ordained. This sentiment was very attractive to
the great noblemen within the Calvinist movement, who hoped by rebelling
against their tyrannical kings to undermine monarchical government and restore
the good old days of feudal decentralization. But significantly, many
Calvinists were professional and business men or small landowners, traditional
proponents of strong kingship and effective central government. These men from
the middle ranks were by no means trying to turn back the clock and weaken the
national sovereign power of the western European states. Quite the contrary.
But they refused to tolerate ungodly kings and magistrates, and they were
prepared to fight for the right to participate in or even control the state.
On the Catholic side, the
Society of Jesus, an order of priests founded in 1540 by St. Ignatius of
Loyola, was almost equally disruptive. Calvin spoke contemptuously of “the
Jesuits and like dregs,” but the resemblance between Calvinist and Jesuit is a
fascinating one. Working from diametrically opposite religious principles,
Loyola and Calvin each built a select, cohesive, extroverted band of zealots.
St. Ignatius devised a systematic emotional and intellectual discipline for the
members of his society, and a highly autocratic, semimilitaristic organization,
directly responsible to the pope. There were a thousand Jesuits by the time of
Loyola’s death in 1556, and sixteen thousand by 1624. But their influence far
transcended their numbers. They established hundreds of schools to teach boys,
especially upper-class boys, how to define and defend the authoritative dogmas
of the Church. They excelled as preachers, and in order to engage the secular
authorities in the counterattack on heresy, they made a specialty of serving as
confessors to Catholic princes. Jesuit militance, autonomy, and busy
intervention in all phases of Church work aroused deep hostility among many
Catholics. To the Protestants, “Jesuitical” meant the same thing as
“Machiavellian,” a curse word for the crafty intrigues and immoral tactics
sponsored by these devilish priests.
The role of the Jesuits was of particular
importance because they were supporters of papal supremacy. The late
sixteenth-century popes, though able and energetic men, could exert little
direct pressure on the Catholic rulers of western Europe. But the Jesuits,
through their schools and confessionals, exercised considerable indirect
influence. Jesuit confessors excelled at casuistry, the art of resolving
difficult cases of conscience. The Protestants liked to believe that they
winked at evil conduct, that their credo was, the end justifies the means. In
fact, the Jesuits were successful at persuading others to fight for the Church
because they fought so courageously them selves. Jesuit missionaries fearlessly
penetrated into Protestant England and hatched a series of plots to depose
Queen Elizabeth. Jesuit pamphleteers in France boldly called for the
assassination of the lukewarm Catholic Henry III and the Huguenot Henry IV.
Despite these inflammatory proceedings, the Jesuits had a generally
conservative concept of the social order. Cardinal Bellarmine (1542-1621), the
most eminent Jesuit writer in the late six teenth century, presented a
nostalgic view of the Christian commonwealth presided over by the pope. But
Bellarmine, like the Calvinists, was no friend to absolute monarchy. In his
view, heretical princes were liable to deposition, and even Catholic secular
authority was distinctly limited.
The Protestant rebellions and Catholic
assassinations of the late sixteenth century forced the proponents of strong monarchy
to develop counter arguments which would bolster the prince’s absolute
sovereign power and make attacks upon him sacrilegious as well as treasonable.
The political theory of the past was of little use on this point. Medieval
theorists had generally denied that princely power was absolute, and the
Renaissance theorists, like Machiavelli, who placed the prince above the law
were too nakedly secular to suit the religious tastes of the late sixteenth
century. It was necessary to devise a new quasi-religious doctrine of
absolutism in order to answer the Jesuits and the Calvinists. The doctrine
which resulted is known as the divine-right theory of kingship. According to
this theory, God appoints the secular sovereign as His earthly lieutenant and
invests him with absolute power over his subjects. The king has no obligation
to obey the laws and customs of his state. He is answerable to God alone. Even
if he rules tyrannically, he is still God’s lieutenant, for God has placed him
on the throne to punish the people’s sins, and their only recourse is to pray
for mercy. The subject has no right to rebel against his anointed king under
any circumstances. This divine-right theory, absurd as it seems today, was very
comforting during the religious wars to devout people who craved peace and
order. It was eagerly adopted by Catholic and Protestant rulers alike, James I
of England preached it; the French kings from Henry IV to Louis XIV practiced
it. So did their Habsburg rivals, and most other seventeenth- century princes.
In the years of religious conflict and
political upheaval between 1559 and 1689, politicians of every stripe invoked
God’s will to suit their particular purposes. The aristocratic and bourgeois
Calvinists found divine sanction for rebellion, constitutionalism, and limited
government. The Jesuits found divine sanction for the deposition of heretical
rulers and a return to papal suzerainty. The secular princes found divine
sanction for absolute monarchy. Radicals found divine sanction even for republicanism,
democracy, and communism. Such were the effects of religion on politics, and of
politics on religion.
SPAIN UNDER PHILIP II
The sixteenth century was Spain’s time of
power and glory. Four great rulers shaped its destiny. Ferdinand (king of
Aragon, 1479-1516) and his wife Isabella (queen of Castile, 1474-1504) were the
founders of modern Spain. Their grandson Charles I (ruled 1516-1556), better
known by his German imperial title of Charles V, was the mightiest European
prince in the early sixteenth century. His son Philip II (ruled 1556-1598) was
the mightiest European prince in the late sixteenth century.
Under Ferdinand and Isabella, the crowns
of Castile and Aragon were joined, the Spanish conquered Moorish Granada, and
Columbus discovered America. Under Charles V, the conquistadores
mastered the Aztecs and Incas and began to mine Peruvian and Mexican silver,
while Spanish armies drove the French out of Italy and won a reputation as the
best soldiers in Europe. During his forty-year reign, Charles was able to spend
only sixteen years in Spain, because of his manifold obligations in Germany,
Italy, and the Low Countries. But his paternalistic style of rule suited the
Spam.ml ., and kept them internally peaceful and stable. In 1556 he bequeathed
lo his son Philip the western half of his immense Habsburg patrimony: the
Spanish kingdoms of Castile, Aragon, and Navarre; the Balearic Islands; several
North African outposts; Sardinia, Sicily, Naples, and Milan; the Netherlands,
Luxemburg, and Franche-Comte; and overseas, Mexico, Florida Central America,
the West Indies, the entire coast of South America except for Brazil (held by
Portugal) and lower Chile and Argentina (left lo the Indians), as well as the
Philippine Islands and numerous smaller Pacific islands. Philip II was really
fortunate not to inherit the eastern Habsburg lands—Austria, Bohemia, and
Hungary—and the Habsburg claims to the Holy Roman imperial title, which Charles
passed to the Austrian branch of the family. Though Philip’s domain was scarcely
unified, it was much more manageable than his father’s had been. It was a
Spanish empire, centered in Madrid, politically absolute, fervently Catholic,
shielded by unbeatable armies, and fed by an apparently boundless supply of
American bullion which Philip’s European rivals bitterly envied.
Sixteenth-century Spain was far from being
a unified nation. Philip II was king of three distinct Spanish states—Castile,
Aragon, and Navarre—each with its own separate institutions, customs, language,
and culture. Philip governed each state independently, but he concentrated his
attention on Castile, the biggest, richest, and most populous of them. Castile
had about seven million inhabitants; Aragon and Navarre together had little
more than one million. Furthermore, Castile was much easier to govern. The
Castilian upper nobility were immensely rich and socially powerful, but
politically harmless. The crown exempted the great magnates from taxation, and
recognized their huge property holdings, and in exchange they refrained from
contesting royal political authority. The lower nobility, or hidalgos,
also exempted from taxation, were useful servants to the crown. Philip II’s corregidores,
royal officials who inspected and regulated the conduct of the sixty-six
principal Castilian town councils, were drawn from the hidalgo class.
The Castilian Cortes, or parliamentary assembly, was very weak. Only eighteen
towns sent representatives, and the nobility and clergy were excluded. Philip
summoned this body often, whenever he wished it to levy taxes, but did not
permit the deputies to share in legislation. In Aragon, on the other hand, the
nobility exercised considerable political power, and the Cortes was more
independent. Philip let the Aragonese nobility alone, summoned the Aragonese
Cortes rarely, and avoided asking for money. Little money could be squeezed out
of Aragon in any case. Nor could Philip’s Italian subjects supply much revenue;
and his subjects in the Low Countries refused to contribute. The king depended
heavily on silver from America, but the brunt of Philip’s imperial
administration was borne by the impoverished Castilian peasantry.
The sprawling Spanish empire was held
together at the top by a remarkably centralized bureaucracy. The king sent
viceroys, generally great Castilian noblemen, to govern his distant
territories, serving as his alter ego. Each viceroy reported to a
supervisory council in Madrid: the Council of Italy, the Council of Flanders,
or the Council of the Indies. Each council was staffed by six to ten
professional civil servants (again mostly Castilians) vested by the king with sweeping
jurisdiction over the executive, judicial, and religious affairs of their
particular territory. There was also a Council of Castile, a Council of Aragon,
and councils to handle matters of state, war, finance, and the Inquisition. The
king himself seldom attended any of these council sessions, but he reviewed all
council decisions and often reversed them. He alone had total information—or as
total as the flood of dispatches, petitions, and memoranda from all parts of
his domain would permit—on every aspect of affairs. Outsiders joked about the
Spanish government’s grave and stately pace of operations, and it is true that
Philip’s elaborate system of bureaucratic checks and balances prevented quick
decisions. But by playing his ministers and councillors off against one
another, the king reduced the possibilities for bribery and corruption, and
also preserved his personal power. As far as any one man could be, Philip II
was master of his empire.
He was certainly master of Italy, though
he never visited his domains there after becoming king of Spain. Philip
controlled half of the peninsula directly, and most of the other Italian states
indirectly. Spanish garrisons in Milan, Naples, and Sicily kept order; the sole
large-scale disturbance during his reign—a Neapolitan insurrection in 1585—was
easily contained. ’ The Spaniards, it was said, nibbled in Sicily, ate in
Naples, and devoured in Milan. From Philip’s perspective, Milan offered the
best fare. This duchy, a major manufacturing center, was the strategic pivot in
his far- flung military defense system and a key recruiting ground for troops
to serve in Mediterranean or northern campaigns. Naples and Sicily, which were
agrarian, were much poorer, without significant trade or exports. Hence Philip
paid more attention to Milan than to his south Italian possessions. In all
three places the Spaniards introduced few changes in local government, ruled in
partnership with the local landed nobility, and enrolled the local peasantry
for Mediterranean campaigns against the Turks. Beyond his own territories,
Philip built political alliances with the dukes of Savoy and Tuscany, and a
business alliance with the merchants of Genoa. In Rome, the nine pontiffs who
ruled successively during Philip’s reign included some very able men who did
all they could to rebuild papal power—and incurred Philip’s hostility in the
process. But these popes seldom dared to challenge the Spanish king directly.
Only the Venetian republic maintained an independent course, and its status was
slipping; in 1571 Venice lost the island colony of Cyprus to the Turks.
Though Spanish rule was not really
burdensome, it had a generally blighting effect on Italian life. Philip’s
policies did little or nothing to remedy the twin Italian disasters of the early sixteenth
century: the political collapse of all the chief city-states save Venice, and
the shill in trade routes from the Mediterranean to the Atlantic. For the
Genoese, however, partnership with the Spanish king was profitable, since they
managed the trade between Italy and Spain and became Philip’s principal
bankers. The sumptuous palaces of the Genoese nobility were mostly built during
the late sixteenth and early seventeenth centuries. In Venice there was still
great wealth and culture, but as the traditional spice trade slumped, the
Venetian capitalists began to withdraw much of their money from risky foreign
ventures in order to invest it in safe farmland. Rome remained a mecca for
pilgrims, artists, and fashionable tourists. The popes, most particularly
Sixtus V (ruled 1585-1590), celebrated the Catholic reformation in stone and
mortar by refurbishing their city on a heroic scale. The basilica of St.
Peter’s, finished in the early seventeenth century, was the largest and most
majestic church in Christendom. But the traveller who ventured a few miles
outside the Eternal City found the countryside infested with bandits. Florence
under the Medici dukes of Tuscany had sadly lost most of its magnificent
creativity, though life for the upper classes remained sophisticated and
gallant. With eleven million inhabitants, Italy was a densely populated region,
almost half again as populous as Spain. Five of the
twelve European cities with populations of more than 100,000 in the late
sixteenth century were Italian. But these cities lacked the business vitality
of the Atlantic entrepreneurial centers. Politically and economically, Italy
had lost its central importance in European life.
Looking westward, Philip II’s management
of his New World colonies demonstrates again the powerful reach of Spanish
royal government. Only a generation before he came to power, a band of tough
and resourceful conquistadores led by Hernando Cortes (1485-1547) and
Francisco Pizarro (c. 1470-1541) had conquered Mexico and Peru, acquired
personal fortunes, and harnessed millions of docile Indians to work for them.
But Charles V and Philip II managed to prevent the conquistadores and
succeeding Spanish colonists from developing political autonomy, carving up
the country into giant feudal estates, or crippling royal power in America. To
control the colonists, the crown sent out Castilian grandees as viceroys of
Peru and New Spain (Mexico). Lest they grow too strong, the crown encouraged
the audiencias, or courts of justice, in the colonies to challenge the
authority of the viceroys. Back in Madrid, the Council of the Indies kept tabs
on both the viceroys and the audiencias. The Church, in partnership
with the crown, protected the Indians from total enslavement by the colonists.
The crown received one fifth of the bullion mined in America, and earned this
royalty by protecting the treasure fleets from attack by French, English, and
Dutch marauders. Philip II’s military power kept his North Atlantic rivals from
establishing permanent colonies in the Indies until after 1600. Sir Francis
Drake could raid the Caribbean audaciously in the 1 570’s, when lie caught the
Spaniards by surprise, but in 1595 he was beaten off Puerto Rico and Panama;
Spanish fortifications there were now too strong for him. No Spanish treasure
fleet was captured until 1628.
The Spanish government insisted on closing
its colonies to outside settlers or traders. Charles V had wanted to open the
Indies to any inhabitant of his Habsburg domain, but this policy was speedily reversed.
Castilians insisted that America—discovered by a Genoese—was their monopoly.
All American commerce had to be funneled through the single Castilian port of
Seville, where it was closely supervised by royal officials in the Casa de
Contratacion (“House of Trade”). Every merchant ship in the American fleet
had to be licensed by the Casa. All incoming and outgoing cargo was
registered with Casa officials, whose most important job was to receive
and distribute the incoming silver and gold. Not only Italian or Flemish
merchants but also Catalan merchants, from eastern Spain, were denied licenses
to trade. Moors and Jews, so unwelcome in Spain that a half million or more
were expelled from the Iberian peninsula between 1492 and 1609, found
themselves rigorously excluded from asylum in America.
Spain’s great weakness, which Philip II
did nothing to correct, was its lopsided
economy. The country was, as it still is, mountainous, barren, and parched.
With a rapid rise in population during the sixteenth century, Spain did not
produce enough grain to feed its people and had to import wheat from the
Mediterranean and Baltic areas. The nobility, who owned almost all the land,
preferred raising sheep to cultivating crops, and merino wool was Spain’s chief
export. The Spanish exported raw wool to Flanders at a low price and imported
finished Flemish cloth at a high price, giving Flemish entrepreneurs most of
the profit. There were no industries to speak of in sixteenth-century Spain;
most manufactured goods had to be imported. The Castilians had always valued
business well below fighting and praying, and much of their commerce and
banking was handled by outsiders. Within Philip’s empire there were three
principal trade routes: between Spain and Italy, between Spain and the Low
Countries, and between Spain and the Americas. The first route was dominated by
the Genoese and the second by Netherlanders; only the American trade was a
closed Castilian preserve, and even here, much of the cargo shipped to America
was non Spanish in origin. In the late sixteenth century, as many as two
hundred ships a year sailed between Seville and the Americas, making this far
and away the busiest single route of European overseas commerce. Bullion
shipments into Seville reached their peak between 1580 and 1620 In 1594, silver and gold accounted for 96 percent of the value of American
exports to Spain. Unfortunately for the Spaniards, little of this treasure
stayed in Spain. Because of the deficiencies in the Spanish economy, it had to
be paid out to foreign farmers, manufacturers, merchants, and bankers.
Philip II’s military power was handicapped
by Spain’s unbalanced economic and social structure. He could not raise enough
money to pay for his large standing armies and his elaborate military
campaigns. Throughout his reign the royal exchequer was in a virtual state of
bankruptcy. Philip inherited large debts from his father, and when he suspended
payment to his creditors in 1557 and again in 1575, he found it harder than
ever to float new loans. He was unable to tap the wealth of his richest Spanish
subjects, for the members of the nobility were exempt from taxes. Three hundred
magnates owned more than half the land in Castile, and the rent-rolls of the
thirteen Castilian dukes and thirteen marquises totaled nearly a million ducats
a year—more than the king’s annual share of American bullion until the 1580’s.
But this money was untouchable. Nor could Philip squeeze much from the Spanish
merchant and professional class, which was notably smaller than that of other
western European states. The only class which he could and did tax with
impunity was the one least able to pay, the impoverished peasantry. In
addition, of course, he spent his American silver as fast as it came in and
even mortgaged future treasure shipments. But Philip’s soldiers consumed all
the American bullion and all the peasant taxes that could be scraped together.
When their pay still fell into arrears, they mutinied and rioted
uncontrollably. An unpaid army is worse than no army at all, as Philip found to
his cost.
The Spanish ardor for fighting and praying
had an old-fashioned flavor, being still largely directed against the
traditional Moorish enemy. One of Philip IPs major taxes was the cruzada,
or crusade subsidy, authorized by the papacy to encourage continued Spanish
warfare against Islam. Spaniards could not understand the general Catholic
agitation for ecclesiastical reform, since the Spanish church had experienced
its own reform movement in the fifteenth century, well before Luther. The
Spanish Inquisition, dating from 1478, had been designed to root out heresy
among converted Moslems and Jews. These conversos were generally hated
and feared, and by the time of Philip II a racist campaign had been launched to
bar anyone from public office whose blood was impure. The Inquisition was the
one institution common to Castile, Aragon, and Navarre, and once the Protestant
revolt broke out, the inquisitors went to extraordinary lengths to keep the new
heresy out of Spain. Anyone deviating in the slightest particular from Catholic
orthodoxy was branded a Lutheran by the Holy Office, subjected to torture and
secret trial, and if found guilty and obdurate, handed over to the secular
authorities for public execution at an auto-da-fe. Erasmus’ supporters
in Spain were hounded into silence. St. Ignatius of Loyola was twice imprisoned
by the Spanish Inquisition on suspicion of heresy. Even the archbishop of
Toledo, the primate of Spain, was held prisoner by his enemies in the
Inquisition from 1559 to 1576 on trumped-up heresy charges. 1 )cspilc this
repressive atmosphere, two late sixteenth-century Spanish mystics, Si Teresa of
Avila (1515-1582) and St. John of the Cross (1542 1591), sparked a new ardor
well illustrated in the rapturous paintings of El Greco (c. 1548-1614). Spanish
rapture did not extend to the papacy. Relations between Madrid and Rome were
continually strained. Like every other prince of his day, Philip was jealous of
outside interference with his territorial church, and besides, “in his heart
he considered religion too serious a matter to be left to the Pope.”
What sort of man was Philip II? He was
outwardly retiring and reserved, yet inwardly secure in his Catholic faith and
his royal majesty. He was slim, sober, and dyspeptic in appearance, spoke
slowly and softly, rarely smiled, was bookish and artistic rather than
athletic, and was happiest when at his desk reading memoranda. He never
personally led his troops on the battlefield. He disliked traveling or
mingling with people, and after 1559 he never left the Iberian peninsula. But
he avidly absorbed all the data his officials could collect. He was a file
clerk on a heroic scale. Every day he sifted through masses of papers, many of
them ludicrously trivial, and wrote voluminous marginal comments, sometimes
correcting errors of grammar and spelling. The king, as some of his subjects
complained, tried to govern the world from a chair. He deeply venerated his
father, but he had none of Charles’s cosmopolitan and ecumenical temper.
Philip II bore more than his share of
private sorrows. He outlived four wives, all married for dynastic expediency,
as illustrated by the fact that at the age of twenty-seven he chose a bride of
thirty-eight, and when she died he married at the age of thirty-two a girl of
thirteen. Six of his nine children died young. His first son, Don Carlos
(1545-1568), was physically deformed and mentally unbalanced. Don Carlos
passionately hated his father, and when the Dutch rebellion began, he tried to
escape to the Netherlands to join the rebels. One night in 1568 the king broke
into his son’s bedchamber with a party of councillors, seized the startled
prince’s weapons and papers, and placed him under armed guard. Philip never saw
Don Carlos again. Six months later, the prince died mysteriously, most likely a
suicide. Philip’s enemies to the north were scandalized by this episode. They
called the king a cruel and secretive murderer. Ever since, Anglo-Saxon Protestant
historians have generally pictured Philip in very dark colors. Spaniards, on
the other hand, affectionately remember him as their Prudent King and prize his
dignified, methodical, and conscientious statecraft. The Spanish view is
obviously closer to the truth, yet Philip’s crusade against Protestantism
turned out to be far from prudent.
Philip II established his court at Madrid,
in the center of Spain. But he craved a solitary retreat where he could escape
from the elaborate court ceremonial and the tiresome audiences with suppliants
and envoys. So he built the Escorial, a vast gray granite structure rising out
of the bleak foothills of the sierras north of Madrid. The building, which took
twenty years to construct, perfectly expresses Philip’s taste and temper.
Behind its severe facade one finds a combination of palace, church, tomb, and
monastery. It is laid out in the shape of the gridiron on which the king’s
patron saint, Lawrence, was supposedly toasted alive. Under the great dome of
the church—one of the first copies of St. Peter’s in Rome—the king buried
various members of his family and prepared his own grave. He found peace and
privacy by going into retreat with the cloistered monks he installed in one
section of the building. There are splendid public chambers in the Escorial,
and a fine library and picture gallery. But Philip’s favorite place was a
meanly furnished little room from whose window he could peep out at the high
altar of his church while Mass was being sung.
Despite his love of solitude and
circumspection, the Prudent King was driven by his zeal and by the military
strength at his disposal to play a strong hand in international affairs. The
first half of his reign was dominated by warfare in the Mediterranean against
Islam, the second half by warfare in the North Atlantic against the
Protestants. On the Mediterranean front, Philip
did very well. Here he sent his army and
navy against the traditional Mohammedan foe. When the Moors in Granada rose in
rebellion in I SM(, royal troops crushed the revolt and forced 150,000 Moorish
prisoner, In resettle in other parts of Spain. Philip fought an inconclusive series
of engagements against the Barbary pirates of North Africa. He could not slop
their raids against the Spanish coast and Spanish shipping, but lie did
strengthen Spanish naval protection for commerce in the eastern Mediterranean.
Behind the Barbary pirates stood the mighty Ottoman Turks. The Ottoman Empire,
like the Spanish, was at its peak in the early years of Philip’s reign. The
Turks occupied three quarters of the Mediterranean shoreline, from the Adriatic
to Algeria, and they were still on the move. They almost took Malta in 1565 and
did take Cyprus in 1571. To save the situation, Philip joined Venice and the
papacy in a Holy League against the terrible Turk.
In October, 1571, a fleet of three hundred
ships and eighty thousand sailors and soldiers (predominantly Spanish) sailed
into the Gulf of Lepanto off the Greek coast to fight an Ottoman navy which had
even more ships and men. The Battle of Lepanto was the biggest naval battle of
the century, a showdown between Europe’s western and eastern giants. Both
fleets consisted of galleys propelled by oarsmen, and they fought in the old-fashioned
close-range style, the men of each galley trying to ram, grapple, and board an
enemy ship. When the Christian fleet closed for action, a crucifix was
displayed in every galley, and all the warriors knelt in adoration as the Turks
came up screaming and trumpeting. After a few hours of ferocious hand-to- hand
combat, the Turkish fleet was annihilated. Three quarters of the Turkish ships,
with their crews, were sunk or captured. Cautious as always, Philip did not
follow up the smashing victory by trying to storm Constantinople. But he had
stopped Turkish expansion, and he had proved who was king of the Mediterranean.
Among the many Spanish soldiers wounded at Lepanto was a young man named Miguel
de Cervantes (1547-1616). Many years later, in the prologue to his Exemplary
Novels, Cervantes proudly described his sacrifice: “In the naval battle of
Lepanto he lost his left hand as the result of a harquebus shot, a wound which,
however unsightly it may appear, he looks upon as beautiful, for the reason that
it was received on the most memorable and sublime occasion that past ages have
known or those to come may hope to know.”
Philip II’s greatest success came in 1580,
when he annexed Portugal and the Portuguese empire. Philip’s mother had been a
Portuguese princess, and when the king of Portugal died in 1580 without a
direct heir, Philip had ;is good a claim to the vacant throne as anyone.
Portugal and Castile had long been bitter political and economic rivals, and
the Portuguese people were strongly anti-Castilian. But by the judicious
distribution of silver and promises of future rewards, Philip’s agents won the
Portuguese nobility mid upper clergy to his candidacy; and more important, the
Spanish king sent in an army to secure the country. In four months his soldiers
overran Portugal, and Philip was soon crowned at Lisbon. His new kingdom was a
small state with only a million or so inhabitants, but by joining the crowns of
Portugal, Castile, Aragon, and Navarre, Philip had seemingly completed the
unification of the Iberian peninsula. Furthermore, the Portuguese empire
overseas was very valuable, second only to the Spanish empire in size and
importance. Philip now had possession of Brazil, the Azores and other
mid-Atlantic islands, slaving stations in Africa, trading posts in India, and
spice islands in Malaysia. Portugal’s Asian spice trade perfectly complemented
Spain’s American silver mines. The Portuguese had no silver of their own, and
they needed Spanish bullion in order to buy spices in Asia. The Spanish
colonists in America wanted slaves from Portuguese Africa, and the Spanish home
government needed Lisbon (a far better Atlantic port than Seville or Cadiz) and
the Portuguese navy and merchant marine.
But the promise of 1580 was never
realized. Philip’s annexation of the Portuguese crown was purely personal and
dynastic. To conciliate the Portuguese, he promised to preserve the country’s
independent institutions and independent commerce and to appoint only
Portuguese officials. No effort was made to break down frontiers nor even to
coordinate Spanish and Portuguese economic policy. Initially, the Portuguese
accepted their new Habsburg ruler without much complaint, but as the years
passed, they saw less and less advantage to the union, especially when the Spanish
were unable to protect the Portuguese colonies from Dutch attack. Thus what
might have been a fruitful permanent partnership lasted for only sixty years.
The annexation of Portugal helped to
direct Philip II’s attention west and north rather than east. Portugal, much
more than Spain, faced onto the Atlantic, and for the first time Philip
possessed adequate naval forces to deal with his Protestant adversaries in the
North Atlantic—England and the Netherlands. Furthermore, in the 1580’s, bullion
imports from America suddenly doubled. Philip was now receiving two million
ducats in silver ingots each year. This chronic fiscal problems seemed less
pressing, and he felt that he could afford more ambitious military adventures
than in the past. Now was the time to deal decisively with a situation which,
from Philip’s viewpoint, had been steadily deteriorating ever since 1559. As we
shall see, the Spanish government had long been trying to suppress heresy and
rebellion in the Netherlands. English privateers had been raiding the Spanish
Indies with rising impudence. The French religious wars had entered a critical
stage. Accordingly, in the 1580’s Philip launched his grand design to solve all
these problems by an overwhelming display of military power. His soldiers and
sailors would quell the Netherlands revolt, invade and conquer England, and end
the French religious wars. The Catholic-Calvinist conflict was reaching its
climax.
THE FRENCH
WARS OF RELIGION, 1562-1598
In striking contrast to Spain, which
enjoyed internal peace and unity during the second half of the sixteenth
century, France was nearly torn apart by forty years of agonizing, destructive
civil war. The French collapse was many-faceted. Huguenots battled Catholics,
aristocratic factions joined together to oppose the crown, the bourgeoisie
strove for new political and religious rights, the Paris mob went wild, and the
outer provinces reverted to their medieval autonomy. Religion was by no means
the only source of trouble, but religion triggered the crisis with explosive
force. The French wars exposed all the latent flaws in sixteenth-century
European civilization. The French, despite their rich cultural resources, their
well-balanced economy, and their impressively centralized governmental
institutions, seemed to lose all sense of social community. The trouble was
partly caused by the size of the country. France was a difficult state to
administer, with a population that climbed during the sixteenth century to
nearly twenty million, more than double the population of Spain. Yet the French
state was certainly more closely knit than the worldwide Spanish empire. A
more obvious trouble in the late sixteenth century was poor royal leadership.
The four Valois kings who followed Francis I (ruled 1515-1547) were all
mediocre, to say the least. Between 1559 and 1589 the queen mother, Catherine
de Medici, was the central figure. Catherine had political talent, but not for
the situation at hand. She tried to play the Huguenots and Catholics against
each other; the result was disastrous for the house of Valois and for France.
During the first half of the sixteenth
century, the French state had the characteristic attributes of a “new
monarchy.” Francis I exercised sovereign authority through his network of royal
officials, through his permanent mercenary army, through his power to levy
direct and indirect taxes. The French representative assembly, the
Estatcs-Gcncral, did not meet between 1484 and 1560. In the outer regions of
the country, the crown negotiated with the provincial estates, much easier to
browbeat than the Estates- General. In central France, where there were no
provincial estates, royal agents annually assessed and collected the gabelle,
or salt tax, and the taille, an income tax levied mainly on the
peasants. The king was master of his territorial church. In the Concordat of
Bologna (1516), the papacy had agreed that all French bishops and abbots were
to be nominated by the crown. Ambitious members of the nobility served as
officers in the royal army, fighting Francis’ frequent wars against Charles V.
This activity not only kept them busy but kept them out of the country as much
as possible. Clearly the tendency under Francis I was toward absolute, centralized
monarchy.
But the king was not all-powerful. The parlements,
or state courts, in Paris and the provinces insisted that he obey the
established laws and to some extent substituted for the Estates-General as a
brake on arbitrary royal power. Border provinces such as Brittany and Burgundy,
only recently annexed to the crown, enjoyed special privileges and exemptions.
The great French magnates had all the rights of the Spanish nobility, including
tax exemption, and they exercised considerable political control over the lieutenants
du roi, or royal administrators, at the local level. The crown was
handicapped by lack of money, despite its taxing power. One sixteenth century
money-making device, the sale of royal offices, tended to hamper the king’s
control over his own bureaucracy; office holding became hereditary and
semifeudal in character. A further complication was introduced when the
religious controversy began to stir men’s minds and emotions. One morning in
1534, good Catholics were horrified to find placards prominently posted in all
the chief French cities, seurrilously denouncing the sacrament of the Mass.
Some daring reformer had even nailed a placard onto the king’s bedchamber door
while he slept in the chateau of Amboise.
Opposition to centralized royal power
began to mushroom during the reign of Henry 11 (1547-15 59). This king was
interested only in hunting and in his elderly mistress, Diane de Poitiers, a
lady twenty years his senior. He was ashamed of his Florentine queen, Catherine
de Medici, (1519-1589), because she came from a “bourgeois” family. At Henry’s
court three rival aristocratic factions—the Guises, the Montmorencys, and the
Bourbons— began to jockey for control of royal policy. All three wanted to
return to the feudal particularism of the good old days, when the great noble
families ruled the various regions of France, and the king was just a
figurehead. But they were bitterly jealous of each other’s efforts to
manipulate the king. The duke of Montmorency, constable of France, had immense
landholdings and a personal retinue of several hundred knights. The Bourbons
were princes of the blood, with the best claim to the French throne should
Henry’s sons leave no heirs. The Bourbon leaders were Louis, prince of Conde,
and his brother King Anthony of Navarre, whose kingdom in the Pyrenees was
mostly in Spanish hands. But the Guise faction was the strongest of the three.
Francis, duke of Guise, was Henry II’s most brilliant general, and his
brothers Charles, cardinal of Lorraine, and Louis, cardinal of Guise, led the
French church. They married their niece (the future Mary, Queen of Scots) to
the royal dauphin, and they persuaded Henry to continue his father’s dynastic
war with the Habsburgs. The heavy war taxes stirred his subjects and sent Henry
deeply into debt. When he finally made peace with Spain in 1559, he had to
renounce all pretensions to Italy. The nobility who had fought in this losing
cause were unpaid and restless. But Henry did not have time to worry about this
problem, for while jousting in a tournament during the celebrations following
the Peace of Catcau Cambresis, he was killed when a splinter from his
opponent’s lance pierced his eye.
The French throne passed successively to
three of Henry II’s sons: Francis II (ruled
1559-1560), Charles IX (ruled 1560-1574), and Henry III (ruled 1574—1589). All
three were feeble and neurotic. All three were dominated by their mother. But
though Queen Catherine de Medici could rule her sons, she could not rule
France. The country dissolved into anarchy and from anarchy into downright war.
The war was ignited by the spread of Calvinism into France. The Huguenots not
only spread heresy but challenged the power and profits of the crown. They were
well organized for political subversion. Working at first in secret, they
established a network of congregations throughout France. Even when Henry II
organized a special court to try Huguenots and have them burned at the stake,
they continued to proliferate. In 1559 they held their first national synod.
They attacked convents and desecrated Catholic churches by smashing the holy
relics and statuary. In 1561 there were 2,150 Huguenot congregations worshiping
openly, with roughly two million adherents—something like 10 per cent of the
population. Their impact was disproportionately great, however, because most
French Catholics were apathetic. Besides, the Huguenots were elite in character
and strategically concentrated in the autonomous fringe provinces: Dauphine,
Languedoc, and Gascony in the south, Poitou and Britanny in the west, Normandy
in the north. Merchants and lawyers, rulers of the provincial towns who were
tenacious of their local privileges, joined in large numbers. Especially in the
south and west, scores of walled towns became Huguenot bastions. Even more striking was the high percentage of converts among the noblesse. About two
fifths of all the French nobility joined tin Huguenot cause. Why should so many
of these proud feudal magnates become smitten with a belief in original sin and
predestination? In truth, few of them had authentic conversions, but they saw a
wonderful chance to reverse the trend toward absolute royal power by
patronizing the new religion. They wanted an arrangement in France similar to
that established in Germany by the Peace of Augsburg in 1555, with each
nobleman con trolling the church in his own lands. When Admiral Coligny, of the
Montmorency faction, and the Bourbon prince of Conde were converted to the new
religion, the Huguenots became a really dangerous political threat.
As early as 1560, Conde and Coligny
hatched a plot to capture the boy king Francis II and “liberate” him from his
Guise advisers. Conspirators converged on Amboise, where the king was staying.
Here in the Loire Valley hunting country, the Valois kings and their courtiers
spent as much time as possible, and here they built their great chateaux,
fortress-palaces with massive battlements and gorgeously fanciful ornamentation
in the Italian style, the finest Renaissance buildings in France. The Guises
foiled the coup d’etat at Amboise and festooned the crenellations of the
chateau with the corpses of the conspirators. But Queen regent Catherine de
Medici prevented the execution of the chief instigators, Conde and Coligny. The
Guises were too powerful to suit her, and she needed the Bourbons as a
counterweight.
Catherine hoped to reduce the tension in
the situation by arranging a settlement which would bury the Huguenot-Catholic
conflict, and in 1561 she actually got Calvinist and Catholic theologians to
attend a joint conference, the Colloquy of Poissy, and tried to make them
subscribe to a common body of doctrine. Having no real religious principles
herself, Catherine supposed that she could paper over the dogmatic dispute. Her
plan, as we shall see, was not far different from the English religious
settlement which Elizabeth I was devising just at this time. But it worked much
less well. In France there was no chance for a latitudinarian church or for
religious toleration as long as both factions believed that they could win
total victory.
The queen’s overtures to the Huguenots
shocked the more fervid French Catholics into taking up arms against
Protestantism. The Guises had always been fiercely anti-Huguenot, and the
religious crisis gave their faction a much wider popularity and a much greater
driving force than it had possessed before. Under Guise leadership, the
ultra-Catholics developed into a power bloc (like the Huguenots) very dangerous
to the Valois monarchy and to the French state. They had the loyalty of Paris,
far and away (lie biggest and most important city. They controlled large
sections of northern and northwestern France, where they could recruit and pay
for large armies. They were backed by the papacy, by the Jesuits, and by Philip
II, who had no love for the Guises but welcomed the chance to exploit French factionalism
to his own advantage. Correspondingly, Elizabeth I of England supported the
Huguenots.
In I 562 the duke of Guise, passing the
little town of Vassy with his troopers, was infuriated to see a congregation of
Huguenots worshiping in a ham, and ordered his men to kill them. This incident
triggered the French religious wars. Once started, the fighting was almost
impossible to stop. The Huguenots formed far too small a minority to conquer
France, but their armies became so expert at defensive campaigns that they
could not be disbanded. Noncombatants suffered more than the soldiers: for
every pitched battle there were numerous forays, Sieges, lootings, and
massacres. Peace treaties were repeatedly arranged only to be quickly broken.
The original commanders on both sides were soon killed, not in battle but by
assassins—the duke of Guise in 1563 and the Bourbon prince of Conde in 1569.
These murders launched a blood feud in which the Catholic and Huguenot zealots
strove for retaliation by ambushing and slaughtering the remaining leaders.
Both sides were able to keep troops in the field for years at a time, their
operations financed largely by tax money diverted from the royal treasury, and
led by vagabond aristocrats who loved fighting and freebooting.
After ten years of inconclusive combat,
the Huguenots seemed to be gaining the upper hand. In August, 1572, during an
interval of peace, the cream of the Huguenot nobility gathered in Paris to
celebrate the marriage of their chief, the young Bourbon prince Henry of
Navarre (1553-1610), to the sister of King Charles IX. Admiral Coligny was
among the celebrants. He had just about persuaded the pliable king to
undertake a major shift in royal policy, to declare war against Spain and
support the revolt of the Calvinists in the Netherlands against Philip II. As a
French patriot, Coligny hoped by this stratagem to end the civil wars and divert
the nobility into fighting their old Habsburg enemies. As a Protestant, he
hoped to secure Calvinism in France and the Netherlands. But Coligny’s plan was
too transparently partisan to attract many non-Huguenots. Obviously young
Henry, duke of Guise (1550-1588), could never agree. Nor was the plan
acceptable to Catherine de Medici, who reckoned that a Franco-Spanish war would
produce victory for Philip II and destroy the Valois monarchy. So Catherine
felt forced to ally temporarily with the Guise faction in order to stop
Coligny. Just what happened next, and why, will always be disputed, for the
evidence is murky and open to diverse interpretations. Someone hired an
assassin to murder the admiral. On August 22, four days after the wedding, the
assassin shot Coligny but merely wounded him. The enraged Huguenots immediately
threatened Charles and Catherine with reprisals, and the wounded Coligny
pressed the king yet again to initiate war with Spain at once, as the only way
to prevent fresh civil turmoil. But Catherine and the Guises had another
solution. Someone—most likely the queen mother—convinced Charles IX that
Coligny and the Huguenots were about to kill him and seize power; the only
escape was to ambush all the traitorous Huguenots immediately and wipe out the
rebel leadership.
Shortly after midnight on August 24, St.
Bartholomew’s Day, armed squads broke into the houses where the Huguenots
lodged. The duke of Guise personally killed Coligny, in revenge for the murder
of his father. Prince Henry of Navarre managed to save his life by promising to
turn Catholic. By dawn the whole hysterical city was taking up the bestial cry,
“Kill! Kill!” Women and children were senselessly hacked to death and dumped
into the Seine. The great scholar Petrus Ramus was cut down while he knelt at
prayer, and his pupils dragged his body through the streets. Debtors murdered
their creditors. Looting continued for days. Such was the St. Bartholomew
massacre, in which at least three thousand Huguenots were killed in Paris. As word
spread throughout the country, another ten thousand were killed in the
provincial towns. Some modern historians, numbed by gas chambers for the Jews
and napalm for the Vietnamese, dismiss the episode as just another atrocity.
But this will hardly do. The St. Bartholomew massacre should be remembered as
mass murder in Europe’s greatest city, plotted by the leaders of the state, and
trigered by religious hatred. When the news reached the pope, he was so
delighted that he gave a hundred crowns to the messenger. Catherine de Medici
laughed exultantly when she saw Henry of Navarre attending his first Mass.
Charles IX, on the other hand, sickened with guilt at having abused his royal
responsibilities. Charles was wiser than his mother, for the massacre discredited
the Valois monarchy without breaking the Huguenots or ending the conflict.
When Charles died in 1 574, he was
succeeded by his even more neurotic brother, Henry III. The new king was
quickly hated for the money and affection he lavished on his mignons, effeminate
court dandies, to say nothing of the degenerate royal ballets and masquerades,
where (according to a scandalized Paris lawyer) the king “was usually dressed
as a woman, with a low-cut collar which showed his throat, hung with pearls.”6
Henry’s feckless extravagance was inherited from his mother, but not his
sudden spasms of religiosity, during which he took up the hermit’s life or
walked barefoot on penitential pilgrimages. Under this last Valois king, the
Catholic-Hugue - not conflict reached its climax. Ultra-Catholics and Huguenots
alike saw Henry as a dissembling hypocrite. They repudiated his efforts at
peacemaking, and did their utmost to dismantle the French state. The Huguenots,
despite their loss of many aristocratic leaders in the St. Bartholomew
massacre, still held important western towns, such as La Rochelle. They were
strongest in the south, and Languedoc became virtually independent. The
ultra-Catholics formed a Holy League in 1576 and vowed to exterminate heresy
and to seat a Catholic champion, such as Henry, duke of Guise, on the French
throne. Leaders of both religions preached rebellion. In the most famous
Huguenot tract, the Vindiciae contra tyrannos, (1578) Calvin’s
political theory was rewritten to show that a tyrannical king has violated his
contract with the people and should be overthrown. Jesuit writers argued the
League position that a king who betrays the Church must be overthrown. Both
sides had strong commanders. For the League, Henry of Guise was a perfect
bandit captain, brave, dashing, and arrogant, with a saber scar etched across
his cheek. But the Huguenots could boast the heir apparent to the throne,
Prince Henry of Navarre, who quickly renounced his forced St. Bartholomew
conversion. Henry of Navarre was an easygoing extrovert with one priceless
virtue: he was the only late sixteenth-century French political leader who
honestly tried to serve his country as well as himself.
The turning point in the French crisis
came in 1588-1589, with the War of the Three Henries: Guise versus Valois
versus Navarre. The conflict began when the duke of Guise made his supreme bid
to capture the monarchy. He had to move carefully, for he was in the pay of
Philip II, who had his own claim to the French throne! (Philip’s third wife had
been a Valois princess.) In 1588 the Spanish king directed Guise to stage a
revolt in Paris in order to prevent Henry III from interfering with the Spanish
Armada when it attacked England. Accordingly, Guise entered Paris against Henry
Ill’s express orders. He incited the city mob to disarm the king’s guards and
besieged him inside the Louvre palace. Before Guise could summon the nerve to
assault the Louvre and kill the king, his intended victim fled the city.
Nevertheless, Guise now had virtual control. He forced Henry III to make him
chief minister, he dictated policy, and he managed the Estates-General which
convened at Blois in 1588. The only trouble was that by this time Guise’s
patron, Philip II, had been badly beaten by the English and was unable to
protect his French agent.
The royal chateau at Blois was Henry Ill’s
last retreat. This rambling palace, with its famous open staircase, myriad
paneled rooms, and secret passageways, lies in the heart of the Loire Valley.
Nearby are Amboise, where Henry’s brother escaped conspiracy, and Chenonceaux,
where his mother squandered a fortune on new construction. Catherine de Medici
could no longer intervene, for she lay mortally ill. Imitating Catherine’s role
in the SI Bartholomew massacre, Henry III plotted to murder Guise. “He does not
dare,” said the duke contemptuously, but for once he underestimated the Valois.
On December 23, 1588, the king’s bodyguard closed in on Guise and cut him
clown. The old queen mother could hear the uproar as the dying duke dragged his
assassins through the royal chambers above her sickbed.
Henry III now joined the Huguenots in an
all-out effort to crush the Catholic League. He threw himself into an alliance
with Henry of Navarre, whom he recognized as his heir, and the two men marched
together against Catholic Paris. But retribution for Guise’s murder came fast:
in July, 1589, Henry III was himself assassinated, by a fanatical monk who had
secreted a dagger in the sleeve of his habit. Only one of the three Henries was
left. Could the French Catholics be induced to accept this heretical prince as
King Henry IV?
The new king’s strongest asset was the
mounting popular revulsion against anarchy. Many Frenchmen, derisively called politiques
because they preferred merely political goals to spiritual ones, had long
craved for peace and stability. The skeptical essayist Michel de Montaigne
(1533-1592) was a politique, disgusted with cannibalism in the name of
divinity. So was the profound political theorist Jean Bodin (1530-1596), whose Six
Books of the Republic (1576) pleaded for the establishment of centralized
sovereign authority in the hands of a purposeful prince. In Henry IV, the politiques
saw at last a French prince who could be trusted with sovereign authority,
who was a statesman of humanity and honesty (unlike Catherine de Medici), with
a suitably jocose, pragmatic temper. Yet it took Henry IV a full decade to end
the war. With Guise dead, the Catholic champion became Philip II, who intended
once lie had conquered Henry IV to put a Spanish infanta on the throne. In the
early 1590’s, Spanish troops repeatedly swept down from Flanders and blocked
Henry IV’s efforts to occupy his capital city. The Parisians continued to
believe their League priests, who taught that a good Catholic would eat his own
children rather than submit to a heretic. In 1593, Henry concluded that he must
undergo the humiliation of abjuring Protestantism. “Today I talk to the
Bishops,” he told his mistress. “Sunday I take the perilous leap” (that is,
attend Mass). Henry’s politically motivated conversion scandalized the
ultra-Catholics even more than the Huguenots, but the pope felt compelled to
grant him absolution. Paris opened its gates to the king who, hat in hand,
saluted all the pretty ladies in the windows as he entered the city.
In 1598, Henry IV and
Philip II finally made peace, restoring the terms of 1559. Spain had gained
nothing. In this same year, Henry bought off the last of the Catholic League
nobility with grants of money and titles and conciliated the Huguenots with the
Edict of Nantes. With this edict, Henry established a lasting religious truce.
He declared Catholicism the official French religion and prohibited the
reformed worship within five leagues of Paris. Yet any nobleman who chose to do
so could practice the reformed religion in his own household, and bourgeois and
lower-class Huguenots could also worship in certain specified places. The
Huguenot residents of some two hundred towns, mostly in the south and along the
Bay of Biscay, were granted full religious freedom,
including the right to set up schools and printing presses. About half of these
towns were fortified and garrisoned by the Huguenots at royal expense. In
addition, Huguenots throughout the country
were promised “perpetual and irrevocable” liberty of conscience, full civil
rights, and eligibility for public office. The king appointed special courts
(half Catholic, half Huguenot) to adjudicate breaches of his edict.
The close of the French religious wars,
with the Edict of Nantes, was to some extent a Catholic victory. France was
henceforth a Catholic country with a Catholic king. Yet Henry IV temporarily
expelled the Jesuits and repudiated the fanaticism of the ultra-Catholic
League. At the same time, his edict was to some extent a Protestant victory,
since it granted the Huguenots an entrenched position within the country. Yet
the Huguenots had lost their leader; toleration was a gift of the king. In most
ways, the compromise of 1598 signalized the triumph of political expediency
over religion. The chief lesson of the French religious wars was a political
one, that strongly centralized government was the only possible alternative to
rebellion and social chaos. Upon this foundation would be built the magnificent
seventeenth-century absolute monarchy of Louis XIV.
THE REVOLT OF THE NETHERLANDS
In the mid-sixteenth century, the people
of the Low Countries had a style of life all their own, distinctly different
from both the Spanish and the French. Theirs was a business society of towns
and merchants, with the highest per-capita wealth in Europe. The Netherlanders
were polyglot, particularistic, and cosmopolitan. Their country was divided
into seventeen autonomous provinces, of which the most important were Flanders,
Brabant, and Holland. Most of the people spoke Low German (Flemish or Dutch),
but the Walloons, who lived in the southern border provinces, spoke a dialect
of French. The Netherlanders lived at the crossroads of northwestern Europe,
where the North Sea coast is intersected by a great river system feeding into
Germany and France. The chief Flemish cloth-manufacturing towns, Bruges and
Ghent, were no longer as prosperous as they had been in the late Middle Ages,
but by the sixteenth century the enterprising Netherlanders were cultivating a
more variegated commercial and industrial pattern. Antwerp was now the biggest
city in the Low Countries and the chief financial and distribution center for
western Europe. English cloth merchants, Portuguese spice merchants, Spanish
wool merchants, German metalware merchants, French wine merchants, Italian silk
merchants, and Baltic grain merchants congregated in Antwerp to exchange
northern and southern products. Antwerp and other Netherlands towns were also
leading industrial centers, and sailors from Zeeland and Holland dominated the
North Sea herring fishery.
The hereditary ruler of the Low Countries
was the duke of Burgundy. From 1506 to 1556, the emperor Charles V had held
this title. The Netherlanders had had little to complain of during Charles’s
long administration, for thanks to the persistence of local customs and
privileges, they had been able to manage their own affairs. The emperor had drawn
heavily on the wealth of his Netherlands subjects in financing li is wars, I
Mil he had left the central administration (such as it was) in the hands of the
high nobility, and the government of the towns in the hands of tin rich
merchants. These merchant oligarchs controlled the provincial estates and the
States-General as well. They refused to grant taxes unless their grievances
were redressed, and they did their own tax collecting, keeping any surplus for
their own purposes. The Netherlands States-General was particularly hard to
handle, because the delegates from all seventeen provinces had to give their
consent before anything could be done. Charles V had been unable to prevent the
influx of Protestantism. Netherlanders were receptive to new religious
opinions; their attitude—as exemplified in their great Christian humanist,
Erasmus of Rotterdam—was tolerant and latitudinarian. Starting in the 1520’s,
Lutheran and Anabaptist doctrines spread widely despite savage heresy-hunting
by Charles’s government.
When Philip II inherited the dukedom of
Burgundy from his father in 1556, he regarded the Low Countries as vital to his
Spanish empire. Antwerp was the chief outlet for Spanish wool and wine, and the
Netherlanders supplied Spain with grain, timber, textiles, armaments, and
mercury for Philip’s silver mines. But Philip soon discovered that the Netherlands
was much harder to govern from a long distance than Milan or Mexico. He
personally disliked the place and never visited there after 1559. He could
speak no Dutch, and had no trusted native advisers. And when he attempted to
correct the atomistic political structure of the Netherlands, he encountered
massive resistance. The people of the Low Countries had seen Charles V as a
fellow Netherlander, but his son was an outsider. The high nobility found that
their power was short-circuited by Castilian bureaucrats in Brussels and
Madrid. Philip was so annoyed by the obstructionist tactics of the
States-General that he vowed as early as 1559 never to convene it again. But
the most explosive issue was religious. By the 1550’s Calvinism was spreading
from France into the Walloon provinces and Flanders. Antwerp became a Calvinist
stronghold. When Philip found that his inquisitors could not eradicate this new
heresy, he summarily reorganized the Netherlands church in 1561 by increasing
the number of bishops from four to eighteen, nominating them all himself.
Philip II’s Spanish absolutism had a
traumatic effect upon the Netherlanders. Shopkeepers turned into soldiers;
cosmopolites turned into patriots; latitudinarians turned into Calvinist
fanatics. But as we shall see, in the end the revolt of the Netherlanders was
only half successful. The seven northern provinces became independent and
Protestant; the ten southern provinces (half Low German and half Walloon)
remained loyal to Spain and to Catholicism. This division was largely
accidental; in the 1560’s the southern provinces were more Protestant and more
rebellious against Philip II than the northern provinces. But accidental or
not, the division became permanent. Between 1560 and 1600 the modern nations of
Holland and Belgium were born.
The revolt against Spain was initiated by
the Netherlands nobility. Three of the highest nobles, the prince of Orange and
the counts of Egmont and Horn, all members of the Council of State, tried
repeatedly to persuade Philip to alter his policy. When they failed, a group of
the lesser nobility petitioned the king in 1566 to abolish the Inquisition in
the Netherlands and to stop persecuting the Protestants. “Why be afraid of
these beggars?” asked a courtier contemptuously, as several hundred gentry
solemnly presented their petition to Philip’s regent in Brussels. And “Long
live the beggars!” suddenly became the rebel cry. Calvinist preachers sprang up
everywhere in the Netherlands and whipped their excited auditors into a rage not
only against the bishops but against all the outward trappings of Catholicism.
In the summer of 1566 hundreds of churches were ravaged by iconoclasts. Some
were converted into conventicles, or meetinghouses, of the Genevan type. This
“Calvinist fury” shocked many Netherlanders and stung Philip into brutal
reprisals. The duke of Alba arrived in 1567 with ten thousand picked Spanish
troops, and lie came very close to crushing all Netherlands resistance to
Spanish absolutism. Alba executed Egmont and Horn, tortured and killed several
thousand suspected heretics, and confiscated their property. He canceled all
meaningful self-government and levied fantastically heavy new taxes. Only a
forlorn band of exiles under the banner of the prince of Orange maintained
active opposition to Philip.
From 1567 on, the Spanish maintained a
formidable standing army in the Netherlands. Warfare in this region of
fortified towns required disciplined, seasoned troops who could handle long
sieges and surprise skirmishes. Alba and his successors mobilized 65,000 men
(and sometimes more) for the campaigns; theirs was the finest fighting force of
its day. Spanish and Italian infantry units were brought north along the
“Spanish road”—the military corridor from Genoa and Milan through Savoy,
Franche-Comte, and Lorraine—to form the core of this army. German soldiers
recruited from the Tyrol, Alsace, and the Rhine Valley, along with local
Netherlands troops, filled out the ranks. Alba’s new taxes by no means paid for
an army of this size, so Philip had to supply most of the funding from Spain.
Between 1567 and 1576 the Spanish spent the equivalent of Elizabeth I’s total
revenue on this army every year, and still many of the soldiers were unpaid.
Here was the fatal flaw in Philip’s military system. Between 1572 and 1607,
units within the Netherlands army staged over forty-five separate mutinies.
They expelled their officers, holed up in fortified towns, lived off the
surrounding countryside, and haggled for months with the Spanish authorities,
until they finally got their back pay. These mutinies repeatedly paralyzed
Philip’s battle plans and stiffened the resolve of the Netherlands rebels.
These rebels lacked cohesion at first. Like the French
Huguenots, they were initially more destructive than constructive. They were
not trying to mold a Netherlands nation-state; each of the seventeen provinces
wanted to preserve its cherished autonomy. Nobility and merchants, Calvinists
and moderate Catholics, could agree only in their distaste for Philip II. From
1567 to 1584 the rebel chief was Prince William of
Orange (1533-1584), a man with many of the same character traits as the
Huguenot chief, Henry of Navarre. Nicknamed William the Silent because of his
skill at masking his intentions, Prince William was actually a gregarious
extrovert who lived grandly and expensively. As a rebel leader he displayed
alarming deficiencies. He was a mediocre general and so personally mired in
debt that merchant creditors refused to lend him enough money. William was a
religious opportunist who changed from Lutheran to Catholic to Calvinist as
the circumstances warranted. In the 1560’s he appeared to be a frivolous
figure. But as he called upon his countrymen to stand up against Spanish
tyranny, he revealed great courage and patriotism. Prince William appealed to
the common people over the heads of the town oligarchs and his fellow nobles,
yet scrupulously avoided grabbing dictatorial power. Almost single-handedly he
strove to harmonize religious, sectional, and class differences, and weave the
Netherlands into a nation. Thanks largely to William, the rebellion progressed,
but it did not culminate in the achievement of his dream, a unified
Netherlands nation-state. Instead, during the 1570’s and 1580’s the seventeen
provinces split into two sections, the rebel north versus the Spanish south.
Religion, which William wore so lightly, proved to be the great divider.
The decisive point came in 1572. In April
of that year, fugitive rebel ships (self-styled “sea beggars”) staged commando
landings in the provinces of Zeeland and Holland, and captured a number of
ports. These sea-beggar rebels had to overcome determined local opposition,
because they were fiery Calvinists invading an area which was still predominantly
Catholic. Having got possession of the territory bordering the Zuider Zee, the
beggars had a permanent base of operations. The Spanish were never able to
recapture Holland and Zeeland, for in this low-lying country the dikes could be
opened to flood an invading army. If Coligny had brought France into the
Netherlands war at this point, and if the English—who later supported the
rebels—had also intervened in force, it is possible that William the Silent and
the sea beggars might have expelled the Spanish from the Low Countries. But the
St. Bartholomew massacre took France out of the picture, and Elizabeth I—well
aware that she lacked money and soldiers—stayed cautiously on the sidelines.
Within the Netherlands, religious and political refugees from the south moved
into the rebel Zuider Zee area in large numbers, and Calvinism became the
established religion. Here was the beginning of the partition of the
Netherlands into two separate states.
In the late 1570’s, William the Silent had
his last real chance to unite all seventeen provinces. In 1576 the Spanish
garrison in the still-loyal southern provinces ran amuck because the soldiers
had been unpaid for two years. They sacked the city of Antwerp and murdered
upwards of eight thousand inhabitants. This frightful “Spanish fury” persuaded
the people of Brabant and Flanders that they must ally themselves with the
rebel north. In 1577 all of the provinces joined the Union of Brussels,
shelving religious disputes and pledging to fight Spain until Philip restored their
privileges and withdrew his troops. William was recognized as their military
commander. Yet the rebels were not effectively united. In 1578 a new Spanish
commander, the duke of Parma, Philip II’s ablest general, appeared on the scene
with fresh troops and new funding based on the rapidly escalating Spanish bullion
imports from America. As soon as Parma began scoring military victories in the
south, he detached the French-speaking Walloon provinces from the rebel
federation. Parma appealed to these southern Netherlander not so much on
linguistic as on religious grounds. How could good Catholics associate with
Calvinists? In 1579 he organized the loyal south into the Union of Arras and
forced William to regroup the Calvinist north into the Union of Utrecht. In
1581 the States-General of the rebel provinces deposed Philip II as their
prince and declared the independence of the United Provinces, or Dutch
republic.
In the 1580’s, each side tried to conquer
the other, with the Spanish nuclei Parma keeping the rebels very much on the
defensive. After Parma had taken the chief Flemish towns in 1584, and Brussels
and Antwerp in 1 585, lie held almost everything south of the Rhine River. A
new wave of religious and political refugees fled north. Philip II hoped that
the seven remaining rebel provinces would surrender if he could eradicate their
leader. He declared William of Orange an outlaw and offered twenty-five
thousand crowns as a reward for his assassination. Several efforts were made to
earn this money, and in 1584 a Catholic fanatic gained entry to the prince’s
house in Delft, stood among a crowd of petitioners, and murdered him at
point-blank pistol range.
With the death of its great founder, the
Dutch republic was truly in desperate plight. The Dutch had so far received
little help from Germany and France, and almost none from England. Now Queen
Elizabeth grudgingly sent a small army under the incompetent earl of Leicester.
For two years (1585-1587), the Anglo-Dutch force precariously held the Rhine
River line against Parma. Philip II, in the Escorial, remembering his mighty
naval victory against the Turks at Lepanto, calculated that another such blow
could crush the Dutch, the English, and the French Huguenots. Accordingly he
prepared a huge new fleet, the “Invincible Armada,” designed to clear the
English Channel and North Sea of Dutch and English shipping, end the revolt of
the Netherlands and the Huguenots, dethrone the heretic queen of England, and
eradicate North Atlantic Protestantism.
ELIZABETHAN
ENGLAND
The British Isles which Philip II prepared
to invade in 1588 offered three strikingly varied scenes. In England, under
“good Queen Bess,” there was peace and prosperity as never before. The English
people, by some alchemy beyond the historian’s analysis, were transforming
their backwater island into a magnificently dynamic society. Scotland, by
contrast, was still half wild. The Scots managed their affairs with crude
abandon. This was the era of the sex-driven Mary, Queen of Scots, and the
hot-gospeling John Knox. Ireland, barely on the edge of civilization, was a
land of perpetual blood feuds and cattle raids, with no real government and no
defense against invaders. During the late sixteenth century, the Irish slowly
fell victim to English conquest and exploitation. Yet in their different
styles, all three peoples experienced the western European religious crisis.
Protestants and Catholics were everywhere vying for control.
When Queen Elizabeth I (ruled 1558-1603)
ascended the English throne, religion was unquestionably the great issue. Back
in the 1530’s, when her father, Henry VIII (ruled 1509-1547), had so easily
separated from Rome, the atmosphere had been worldly and cynical. Henry had
invited the nobility and gentry who sat in Parliament to legislate the break
with the papacy, giving them a larger share of power, and had then sold the
confiscated Church lands to them cheap. In those days only a few Englishmen,
such as Sir Thomas More, had been willing to die for the old universal Church.
Only a few Englishmen, such as William Tyndale, who translated the Bible into
English, had been outspoken proponents of Luther’s new doctrines. But by the
1550’s the atmosphere was much changed. During the reign of Elizabeth’s feeble
brother Edward VI (1547-1553), radical Protestants had overhauled the doctrine
and ritual of the English church. In the succeeding reign, Elizabeth’s fervidly
Catholic sister, Queen Mary Tudor (1553-1558), had forcibly reunited the
English church with Rome and burned at the stake the several hundred persons
who dared to protest. This short period of violent fluctuation, reminiscent of
the period of Valois rule in France, aroused deep religious passions in the
English people. Would Elizabeth follow Edward’s example, or Mary’s?
She did neither. Queen Elizabeth I was the
only ruler in western Europe in the late sixteenth century who was able to
handle the religious issue. Despite the loud fulminations of Calvinists and the
conspiracies of Catholics, she unerringly pursued a policy of peace and
compromise, and got away with it. This achievement alone is good reason for
nominating Elizabeth the ablest politician of her time. Certainly she was more
attractive as a queen than as a human being. She had a temper to match her red
hair and a tongue to match her sharp features. Superficially, she was
vacillating, evasive, and vague, but she was willfully stubborn underneath. Her
unfortunate councillors had to take the blame for whatever went wrong. She was
frugal, not to say mean, in her expenditures; though she paid plenty for
clothes and cosmetics, she allowed her devoted courtiers to buy her entertainment,
without offering in return the royal pageantry supplied by Catherine de Medici
or public monuments like Philip II’s Escorial. In an age when government was
reckoned to be strictly a man’s job, Elizabeth refused to marry because she
would not share power, but kept the bachelor princes of western Europe dangling
as her suitors. In an age when women were reckoned to be fit chiefly for
childbirth, and queens for the production of male heirs, Elizabeth made a
virtue of her spinsterly virginity, while behaving with ever more outlandish
coquetry the older she got. And yet, she was one of the greatest rulers In
English history.
Elizabeth’s I’s first and most important
work was her religious settlement, achieved between 1559 and 1563. The new
queen was confronted with a church staffed by her sister Mary’s Catholic
appointees, with the clamors for reinstatement of her brother Edward’s ousted
Protestant clergy (many of whom had returned from exile in Geneva and other
Calvinist centers), and with a Parliament divided between the Catholic House of
Lords and a Protestant House of Commons. Queen and Parliament worked out a compromise
reorganization of the Church of England so as to combine an external Catholic
structure with a broadly Protestant dogma. The intention was to satisfy as wide
a spectrum of religious tastes as possible. All Englishmen were required to
attend public worship in the national church, but no man’s inner conscience was
publicly scrutinized. Under the Elizabethan system, there was no
heresy-hunting, no Inquisition, no burnings, only a system of fines for those
who stayed away from church. Less than 5 per cent of the clergy resigned (they
were replaced, of course, by Protestants); the remainder docilely subscribed
to the required Thirty-nine Articles of belief, a formula closer to Luther than
to Calvin, which listed numerous “errors” in the Roman Church. The queen hand
picked her bishops and sometimes kept bishoprics vacant for years in order to
tap the revenues: the Elizabethan church was decidedly subordinate to the
state. Men of strong conviction were of course offended by the expediency of a
church which in its prayer book could describe the pivotal Communion service
both as a miracle and as a memorial ceremony. But only the most radical
Calvinists and the most committed Catholics refused to tolerate the dignified
beauty of the Anglican liturgy, and soon many Englishmen were deeply loyal to
their via media.
Having worked out a formula for English
religious stability and peace, Elizabeth I spent the rest of her long reign
trying to keep the status quo. She was a political conservative, and
with good reason. England, after all, was a small state with a population of
less than four million and a predominantly agrarian economy. The income of the
royal government was very modest by Spanish or French standards. The queen
could afford neither a standing army nor an elaborate civil service. She
depended on the cooperation of the nobility and the landed gentry. The English
nobility were less wealthy than their Spanish or French counterparts and
enjoyed fewer privileges; they even paid taxes.
Henry VII and Henry VIII had done a great deal to
domesticate the feudal magnates who had controlled England in the late Middle
Ages. But under Elizabeth the nobility still exercised great power: they commanded
small armies of retainers, they sat in the House of Lords and got their
adherents elected to the House of Commons, and they formed aristocratic
factions at court dangerously similar to the Guise and Bourbon factions in
Valois France. Like earlier Tudor monarchs, Elizabeth tried to bolster her
position with respect to the nobility by patronizing the upper middle class:
country squires and London merchants. She chose her two chief advisers—Sir William Cecil (1520-1598) and Sir Francis Walsingham
(c. 1530-1590)—from this class, and on the local level appointed deserving
squires as justices of the peace. The justice of the peace received no pay,
but. he had dignity, responsibility, and control over neighborhood affairs.
When his interests coincided with those of the royal government, he served the
queen very well.
The most obvious brake on English royal
authority was Parliament. Elizabeth could neither tax nor legislate except
through Parliament. Unlike the Castilian Cortes and the French Estates-General,
Parliament gained power steadily throughout the sixteenth century. Henry VIII,
Edward VI, Mary, and Elizabeth all worked through Parliament in their attempts
to shape the English church. Much more legislation was enacted by Parliament
during the Tudor era than in the Middle Ages. Parliamentary taxes were vital to
the crown, and Elizabeth (unlike Philip II in Castile) had great difficulty in
wheedling tax levies from Parliament even in emergencies.
In the early sixteenth century the lower
house, the House of Commons, had been more tractable than the House of Lords,
citadel of the nobility, but under Elizabeth, the Commons became the more
independent and aggressive of the two houses. Ambitious and well-connected
country gentlemen actively sought election to the Commons. Elizabethan parliamentary elections
bore little resemblance to modern ones. There were no parties or platforms.
Most elections were uncontested. Only candidates of high social standing,
wealth, and influence presumed to stand, and they were dutifully accepted by a
few hundred subservient voters. But if the electorate was subservient, the
members of Parliament were not. Elizabeth was hard pressed to cope with the
opinionated, self-confident gentry who crowded into the Commons chamber in St.
Stephen’s Chapel at Westminster, just outside the city of London, in order to
question her policies and advocate their own. The queen summoned Parliament as
infrequently as possible, convoking it for a session of a couple of months
every three or four years. Her ministers carefully stage-managed every bit of
business, but they could not prevent rude speakers in the Commons from urging
Her Majesty to marry or to crush popery. Even though the government introduced
legislation, members of the Commons freely debated and amended bills in
committee and introduced new bills of their own. The queen became adept at
seeming to surrender to Parliament, while still preserving her prerogative.
There was always a Puritan bloc in
Parliament. Puritans were the English species of Calvinist. They wanted to
cleanse the English church of its popish ceremonies and ritual, to abolish
Elizabeth’s episcopal church government, to erect a preaching ministry and a
national Geneva discipline. The Puritans were less rebellious against the
government than were their compeers in France and the Netherlands. Much as they
disliked the queen’s lukewarm Protestantism, they accepted membership in the
Church of England and aimed at purifying it from within. Hence the Puritans
were less easy to identify than were the Huguenots and the Dutch Calvinists. Indeed,
many Anglican clergymen, including several bishops, were Puritans. The movement
was attractive to articulate, educated laymen, and an increasing number of
landed gentlemen and London merchants became Puritans. Cambridge University
was the intellectual headquarters of the Puritans. Elizabeth intensely
disliked Puritan criticism of her church. She took special pains to gag Puritan
polemicists and kept the movement relatively small. But even Elizabeth could
not stop the prolific Puritan pamphleteers from formulating belligerent
protests against prayer books, bishops, and godless rulers, developing a line
of argument which would lead—a generation after the queen’s death—to the
Puritan Revolution of 1640.
In the short run, the biggest challenge to
the status quo came not from the radicals in religion, but from the
conservatives. The Catholics had a very active claimant to the English throne
in Mary Stuart, better known as Mary, Queen of Scots, who was everything
Elizabeth was not: beautiful, alluring, passionate, and rash. Mary’s reign in
Scotland (1561-1567) was brief and turbulent, and suggests the chaos that might
have engulfed England had she been able to take her cousin Elizabeth’s place.
To be sure, sixteenth-century Scotland was not an easy place to govern. The
wildly beautiful countryside was economically underdeveloped. The few small
towns were frequently overrun by marauders despite their grim gray stone walls.
The Scots nobility were untamed tribal chieftains, continually feuding and
fighting among themselves. Roughly half the people were Catholics; the other
half, Calvinists. The Calvinist leader was John Knox, a brass-tongued preacher
whose “Reformed Kirk” was patterned after the Genevan presbyterian system. The
General Assembly of the Reformed Kirk was a more powerful body than the Scots
parliament, for it was quite independent of royal control. Mary Stuart had been
queen of Scotland since she was an infant, but she had spent her girlhood at
the French Valois court, her mother governing Scotland as regent until she died
in 1560. One foggy, dismal day in 1561 the nineteen- year-old queen returned
from France to Holyrood Palace, in Edinburgh, to be greeted by a serenade of
psalms sung out of tune. She was already a widow; her first husband, the boy
king Francis II of France, had died the previous year. Mary established as gay
a court as possible at Edinburgh and won over many of the Protestant nobility.
But her charms cast no spell on John Knox. Mary reportedly told Knox, “1 will
defend the kirk of Rome, for it is, I think, the true kirk of God.”
“Your will, madam,” came the reply, “is no
reason: neither doth your thought make that Roman harlot to be the true and
immaculate spouse of Jesus Christ.”
Mary had no desire to settle permanently
in dour Scotland. She immediately pressed Elizabeth to recognize her as heir
to the English throne, and when Elizabeth procrastinated, she married her
cousin Henry Stewart, Lord Darnley, who had the next-best claim to the English
throne. But Mary soon lost interest in the empty-headed Darnley and adopted a
court musician named David Rizzio as her paramour. Early in 1566 the jealous
Darnley gathered a band of conspirators who surprised Mary and Rizzio at supper
in Holyrood Palace and hacked Rizzio to death as he clung to the queen’s
skirts. Mary shortly got her revenge. When Darnley contracted smallpox, she
installed him in a lonely house outside the walls of Edinburgh, and one night
someone strangled Darnley and blew up his house with gunpowder. Who did it can
never be proved, but most Scotsmen at the time suspected the earl of Bothwell,
Mary’s latest lover. Their suspicions became firmer when Mary married Bothwell
three months after Darnley’s murder. The question of Mary’s guilt or innocence
in this lurid affair has been endlessly debated. One fact is plain. By marrying
Bothwell she lost control of Scotland. The nobility revolted against the lady
and forced her to abdicate. In 1568 she fled to England, and Elizabeth
imprisoned her.
Mary was still young, still bewitching. In
1569 a band of Catholic lords led an abortive rebellion on her behalf in
northern England. The 1570’s and 1 580’s were marked by a series of Catholic
plots to assassinate Elizabeth and enthrone Mary—all discovered (and some
perhaps planted) by Elizabeth’s spies. The pope had excommunicated Elizabeth, and
resolute Jesuit missionaries, such as Edmund Campion and Robert Parsons, were
encouraging the remaining English Catholics to stand firm in their faith. The
queen and her ministers felt compelled to crack down: during Elizabeth’s reign,
over two hundred priests and Catholic laymen were executed on the technical
charge of treason. In 1586, government spies uncovered Mary’s complicity in a
new assassination plot. This time she was tried and found guilty. With a great
show of reluctance, partly real and partly feigned, Elizabeth signed the death
warrant. In 1587, Mary Stuart was released from her nineteen years of
imprisonment by the executioner’s axe. Catholics naturally saw her as a martyr
and denounced the Protestant Jezebel for murdering an anointed queen.
Religion was one of the causes of mounting
friction between Elizabethan England and Philip II’s Spain. Another was
Elizabeth’s support of the Dutch rebels. A third cause, perhaps the most
decisive, was English intrusion into the Spanish empire in America. Until the
mid-sixteenth century, English sailors had taken practically no part in the
exploration and exploitation of the New World, and English merchants were
perfectly content with the traditional
Flemish wool trade. By the 1560’s, however, even
Englishmen were becoming interested in the possibility of finding wealth in the
New World. Elizabeth I encouraged private investment in overseas enterprises and
offered token investments herself. Sailors from Plymouth and other southwestern
ports began to reconnoiter the Atlantic. Some, such as Martin Frobisher and
John Davis, searched the still unclaimed North American coastline, looking
fruitlessly for a passage to Cathay, and panning fruitlessly for gold. Others
ventured into the Spanish Caribbean. Between 1562 and 1568 John Hawkins sold African slaves to the Spanish planters with some
success. Between 1571 and 1581 Francis Drake (c. 1540-1596), a fiery
Protestant, made three piratical raids on Spanish America with much greater
success. On his third voyage, Drake took his ship, the Golden Hind,
through the Strait of Magellan, captured a Spanish treasure ship off the
Pacific coast of South America, then sailed up to California and from there to
the South Pacific spice islands and to the Cape of Good Hope; thus, when he
returned to Plymouth after an absence of three years, he had circumnavigated
the globe. The queen knighted Drake in 1581, and no wonder; his cargo of
Spanish treasure was worth twice Elizabeth’s annual revenue. In 1585-1586, with
the official backing of his government, Sir Francis took a big fleet of thirty
ships once more into the Caribbean, where he vandalized the Spanish more than
lie plundered them. Certainly the Elizabethan sea dogs were doing all they
could to provoke the Prudent King.
So it was that the two most cautious
leaders in Christendom, both fearful of change and sensitive to the burdens of
war, faced each other in dramatic conflict. In 1586, Philip II began to plan
his invasion of England. A Spanish fleet, powerful enough to hold the English
navy at bay, was to sail from Lisbon to the Flemish coast, rendezvous with
Parma’s army, assembled on barges, and cross the English Channel, landing at
the month of the Thames. Even with the
best of luck this plan would have been extremely difficult to execute, and one
misfortune after another compounded the difficulty. In 1587, Sir Francis
Drake daringly raided Cadiz, Spain’s chief Atlantic port. He sank enough ships
to delay Philip’s enterprise by a year and destroyed the Spaniards’ precious
store of seasoned barrel staves, thereby condemning the Armada crew to a diet
of stinking water and spoiled food as a result of storage in casks made of
green timber. Then, on the eve of embarkation, Philips admiral died. His replacement, the duke of Medina-Sidonia was brave but
inexperienced.
The Invincible Armada that finally neared
the English coast in July, 1588, was a majestic fleet of 130 ships and thirty
thousand men. The English sailed out from Plymouth with an equally impressive
force. They had as many ships as the Spaniards, their seamanship and their guns
were better, and they had Sir Francis Drake. This was not the biggest naval
showdown of the century. Twice as many ships and men had fought at Lepanto in
1571. But the Battle of Lepanto was a land battle transferred to sea, with
soldiers swarming across oared galleys which had locked together. The Anglo-Spanish
confrontation in 1588 was altogether, different, a mariners’ duel between
sailing ships armed with cannon. The Armada fight inaugurated the classical age
of naval warfare, which stretched from the sixteenth into the nineteenth
century, from Drake to Nelson.
The Spanish and English fleets met off
Cornwall, at the southwestern tip of England. Both sides were reluctant to
attack. The duke of Medina-Sidonia was dismayed to see how nimbly the English
could sail around his ships. The English were baffled by the tight Spanish
crescent formation, designed to force them to grapple at close quarters, to
fight in the style of Mediterranean galleys, by ramming and boarding, at which
the Spanish excelled. For nine days the two fleets drifted slowly up the length
of the Channel, the English buzzing around the Spanish crescent, neither side
doing much damage. Medina-Sidonia was approaching his rendezvous with Parma,
but so far he had been continuously outmaneuvered, and he saw that if he tried
to convoy Parma’s men in barges from Flanders across the Channel to England,
the English navy would lacerate them. He anchored off Calais, trying to think
of some way to join forces with Parma. All at once, disaster struck the Armada.
At midnight the English sent eight blazing fire ships into the Spanish fleet.
The Spanish ships scattered to sea, their crescent formation broken. Drake and
his comrades pounced on them, sank some of the ships, and pounded the rest
until ammunition gave out. Then a gale swept the battered Armada into the North
Sea. Medina-Sidonia had lost all hope of joining with Parma or invading
England. With the English fleet chasing him north, toward Scotland, he sailed
his limping, leaky galleons around the British Isles. A number of ships and
thousands of men were lost off the stormy Irish coast. About half the fleet
eventually straggled back to Spain. So ended the first modern naval battle. So
ended Philip’s plan to dethrone Elizabeth.
THE
DECLINE OF SPAIN
The defeat of the Spanish Armada was a
decisive event. It exposed the limitations of sixteenth-century military power.
It stamped Philip IPs overweening international policy with failure. It tipped
the religious struggle, which underlay all western European politics during the
late sixteenth century, in favor of the Protestant minority. And it closed
Spain’s golden century of power and glory.
After 1588, nothing went right for Philip
II. The Spanish king received the news of the Armada’s defeat with his
customary sober stoicism—and kept on trying to conquer England and put down the
Dutch rebels. In the 1590’s, as has been mentioned, he took on a new opponent,
invading France in an attempt to dethrone Henry of Navarre. The French,
English, and Dutch formed an alliance against him, fought him to a standstill
on land, and bested him at sea. The Spanish infantry was still superlative, and
in northern France the duke of Parma campaigned with his usual brilliance
against Henry IV. But his successes roused French patriotism against the
Spanish invaders. Unwittingly, Philip II helped Henry IV to reunite his country
and restore the centralized power of the French monarchy. In 1598, just a few
months before his death, Philip reluctantly made peace with Henry. Though this
peace treaty restored the status quo of 1559, psychologically it was a
French victory, the first of a long series of Bourbon victories over the
Habsburgs. Within a few years the agony of the French religious wars became
only a memory, as Bourbon France rapidly eclipsed Habsburg Spain in political
and military power.
Philip II never made peace with England.
The Anglo-Spanish war continued until 1604, with the English inflicting more
damage than they received. Despite the failure of the Armada, Philip doggedly
kept trying to invade Britain. His last great fleet, headed for Ireland, was
dispersed by storms in 1596. Through the years, the English countered by
launching a series of armadas against Spain but never came close to achieving a
knockout blow. In 1589, Sir Francis Drake failed to capture Lisbon; in 1596, he
died while leading an abortive attack against the Spanish West Indies. The
English did score some victories. In 1596, they sacked Cadiz and pillaged the
surrounding Spanish countryside. Throughout the war, English privateers
mercilessly plundered Spanish commercial vessels. On the whole, the long war
cast a damper on the buoyant Elizabethans. They were spending too much blood
and money for too little glory. Yet England emerged from this conflict in far
better shape than Spain and with new ambitions for an empire of its own to
rival the Spanish empire.
Philip II’s bitterest legacy was the
Netherlands rebellion. In the mid- 1580’s, Parma seemed close to reconquering
the northern provinces, but his participation in the Armada fiasco and in
campaigns in France against Henry IV between 1589 and 1592 killed Spanish
momentum in the Netherlands. Lack of sea power was also very damaging. When the
Flemish farmers had three poor harvests in a row, the Anglo-Dutch naval
blockade stopped all grain imports and triggered the worst famine of the
century in the southern provinces. After 1590 every Spanish campaign was
crippled by mutinies. The fighting continued until 1609, with neither side able
to penetrate far beyond the Rhine River line which divided the seven Calvinist
United Provinces from the ten Catholic provinces in Spanish hands. The Dutch
commander, Prince Maurice of Nassau, son of William the Silent, hoped to
reunite the northern and southern provinces, but many of his Calvinist
supporters did not wish to join with Catholics, and the burghers of Holland and
Zeeland did not wish to share their business prosperity with the towns of
Flanders and Brabant. The northern provinces flourished mightily during the
war; the south was in economic collapse. After Parma captured Antwerp in 1585,
Amsterdam, the chief northern port, quickly became the leading entrepot in the
Low Countries. The Amsterdam businessmen did not want Antwerp’s old primacy
restored. Accordingly, even after the Spanish and Dutch arranged a twelve-year
truce in 1609, the Dutch insisted on blockading the Scheldt River, Antwerp’s
avenue to the sea. The war reopened in 1621, and this time the Dutch clearly
gained the advantage. Prince Frederick Henry, the youngest son of William the
Silent, was now the Dutch general, and he pushed the Spaniards well south of
the Rhine. But the great Dutch successes were at sea. The purpose of the Dutch
West Indies Company, founded in 1621, was to plunder Spanish America. Company
ships captured the Spanish silver, fleet in 1628. By 1636, they had taken 547
enemy vessels. In 1648, Spain capitulated, and after trying for eighty years to
overcome the Dutch, finally recognized the independence of the United
Provinces.
By this time, Spain and its empire had
sadly decayed in wealth and vigor from the great days of the sixteenth century.
The decay could be found at all levels of Spanish society. Philip IPs
successors—Philip III (ruled 1598— 1621), Philip IV (ruled 1621-1665), and
Charles II (ruled 1665-1700) —were feckless kings, unable or unwilling to
sustain the Prudent King’s grasp on the central institutions of government. The
population shrank, and there was a severe slump in the production of wool,
Spain’s chief export. The peasants were less able than ever to pay the high
taxes their government demanded. The merchant marine never recovered from the
shipping losses inflicted by English and Dutch privateers. Apathy set in,
extending even to the New World. American silver production fell precipitously,
until by 1660, bullion shipments to Seville were only 10 per cent of what they
had been in 1595. In Spanish America, the Indian population decreased, towns
decayed, and the colonists fell back on a subsistence agricultural economy
closely parallel to that of the mother country. Old Spain and New Spain no
longer had much to contribute to each other. Though the empire remained
technically closed to outsiders, the home government was helpless to prevent
the intrusions of foreign traders. It is estimated that during the second half
of the seventeenth century, two thirds of the European goods sold to Spanish
Americans were smuggled in by Dutch, English, or French interlopers. These
illicit traders did not plunder the Spanish Main as the Elizabethan sea dogs
had once done. Instead, by punctiliously bribing the local Spanish officials,
they gained permission to offer their wares to the colonists, who bought
eagerly because the smugglers (having evaded Spanish customs taxes) undersold
the Seville monopoly. Economically, the Spanish empire had disintegrated.
The Spaniards remained as proudly
autocratic, devout, and introspective as ever. Indeed, as their political power
evaporated, they became ever more sensitive to questions of status and honor.
And war remained the chief field of honor.. There were only twenty-eight years
during the seventeenth century when Spain did not have armies in combat. It
fought five wars with France alone. The net result of all this fighting was
that Spain had to cede territory in the southern Netherlands, the Pyrenees, and
Franche-Comte to the French, and yield a number of small Caribbean islands to
the English, French, and Dutch. The strain of war precipitated a chain of
mid-seven teenth-century rebellions within the Spanish empire. Portugal rose up
in revolt in 1640, and after long years of fighting, Spain recognized its independence
in 1668. Rebellions in Catalonia, Naples, and Sicily were suppressed with
difficulty. This cumulative tale of defeat and decay is not easy to explain. A
formula which had worked well in the sixteenth century stopped working in the
seventeenth. Philip II can be blamed for overstraining the Spanish system, but
he can hardly be blamed for his people’s collective loss of vitality. Spaniards
were no longer swashbuckling conquistadores; somehow, after 1588 they
lost the knack of remaking the world.
Philip IPs defeat and Spain’s decline
signalized the collapse of the Catholic crusade against Protestantism in
western Europe. The ancient unity of western Christendom had been smashed beyond
redemption. Yet the Calvinist crusaders had not won an outright victory. By
the time Philip died in 1598 it was apparent that neither side could conquer
the other. The French religious wars resulted in a compromise: king and country
remained Catholic, while the Huguenots enjoyed political autonomy and
religious liberty. The Netherlands revolt also resulted in a compromise: the
north became predominantly Calvinist and politically independent, while the
south remained Catholic and Spanish. In England, yet another kind of
compromise emerged, with both Calvinists and Catholics forced to accept a
state-controlled latitudianarian church. These compromise settlements can be
interpreted as moral triumphs for the Calvinists, since they had fought the
Catholics, despite their far greater political and military resources, to a
standstill. But the Calvinists in France and England had not achieved their
Genevan ideal, and in the Dutch republic the Calvinist zeal of the 1560’s was
already turning by 1600 into a secular zeal for making money. Except in
England, Calvinism had passed its most militant phase by the end of the
century. The most effective leaders of the late sixteenth century—Henry IV,
William the Silent, and Elizabeth I—were all politiques who did their best
to bury the religious issue and keep the church subordinate to the state.
It would be a great mistake, however, to
dismiss the Calvinist-Catholic conflict as unimportant because neither side
won. Though the religious ideals of Calvin and of Loyola were quickly diluted
in practice, the impact left by these sixteenth-century crusaders was strong
and lasting. They strengthened the moral purpose and community spirit of every
western European state. For the Spanish people, the sixteenth century was the
golden age, illuminated by a fusion of missionary zeal, military prowess, and
artistic creativity which they were never afterward able to match. For the
French, Dutch, and English, the greatest days lay ahead. In the seventeenth
century these three peoples would dominate Europe and give the world new
definitions of individual liberty and public order, of individual prosperity
and public power.
Chapter 2
Political Disintegration in Central and Eastern Europe
Rudolf
II. Vegetable portrait of the emperor
by Guiseppe Arcimboldi. Rudolf, a patron of the arts, is said to have admired
this painting. Nationalmuseum, Stockholm.
St.
Michaelskirchc, Munich. The architect
has boldly employed Renaissance statuary, arches, columns, and entablatures
to achieve a vigorous yet balanced ensemble. This is the Mannerist style,
prefiguring the Baroque. In the right rear is seen one of the Gothic
Frauenkirche’s capped towers.
Service in a German Reformed Church. Note the disciplined Calvinist austerity of this scene, set in a bare
hall, with the women (center)
segregated from the men (right and left), the elders seated forward by the
communion table, and all attention riveted onto the open Bible and the preacher
in his pulpit. Germanisches Nationalmuseum, Nuremberg.
Palm Sunday
in Moscow. This seventeenth-century
engraving shows a religious procession emerging from the Kremlin. St. Basil’s
Cathedral, with its spectacular display of nine onion domes, is to the left.
Ivan the
Terrible. This old print presents
evidence that the prince was well named.
Gustavus
Adolphus. Pencil sketch by Strauch,
drawn in the year of the Swedish king’s death. Nationalmuseum, Stockholm.
Catholic reentry into Augsburg, 1629. The Protestant cartoonist shows two devils vomiting parish priests
(left) and Jesuits (right) into the city.
Caricature
of the Swedish army which invaded Germany in 1630. Gustavus Adolphus’ soldiers are represented as barbarians from
Lapland, Livonia, and Scotland, bent on rape and plunder. The Livonian is
mounted on a reindeer.
Soldiers pillaging a farmhouse. By
Callot. Some of the troopers torture the farmer over his kitchen fire to find
where the money is hidden, while others rape the houshold women and steal food.
The
Treaty of Munster in 1648 between Spain and the Netherlands. Painting by Ter Borch. This treaty, in which
Spain finally recognized the independence of the Dutch Republic, was part of
the general peace settlement of 1648. In the painting, the Dutch delegates
swear the oath of ratification with hands upraised, while the Spanish delegates
(right center) place their hands on a
Bible.
Leopold I
of Austria. Engraving by van
Dryweghen. This Hahsburg emperor looks less than handsome because of his
protruding jaw, a common trait in his family, caused by generations of
inbreeding within the Habsburg dynasty.
The Prussians swearing homage to the Great Elector at Konigsberg, 1663. The Prussian estates long refused to admit
that the Elector had sovereign power over them, but finally in 1663 he
persuaded them to pledge allegiance to him as overlord.
The wars of religion engulfed Latin
Christendom, central and eastern as well as western Europe. Germany, birthplace
of the Protestant Reformation, was a battleground between the 1520’s and the
1640’s. Switzerland, Bohemia, Poland, Hungary, and Transylvania were all
religiously divided, with Catholics, Lutherans, Zwinglians, Calvinists, and
Anabaptists pitted against one another. The Austrian Habsburgs, like the
Spanish Habsburgs in the west, were Catholic champions; Gustavus Adolphus of
Sweden was the chief Protestant leader. Yet the Protestant-Catholic conflict in
Germany, and elsewhere in central and eastern Europe, took on quite a different
style from the crusading ardor of the Atlantic peoples. East of the Rhine, the
motives for fighting were less “religious,” indeed in every sense less
ideological. Protestants and Catholics exhibited less sense of moral
regeneration, less missionary zeal, than did their counterparts in the west,
and a stronger preoccupation with territorial aggrandizement. The Thirty Years’
War, biggest of all the wars of religion, was fought for more obviously secular
objectives than were the French and Dutch religious wars. It was also more
destructive of life, property, and social vitality. How ironic that Luther’s
compatriots should suffer more damage, to less purpose, in the name of
Protestant-Catholic rivalry than any other European people!
Political, social, and cultural factors
help explain why the religious crisis of the sixteenth and seventeenth
centuries worked out so differently east of the Rhine. In central and eastern
Europe, the concept of state sovereignty at the national level had not yet
developed as it had in France, England, and Spain. Political units were
simultaneously larger and smaller than in the west. The Holy Roman Empire, the
Ottoman Empire, Poland, and. Russia were each much larger than any western
national state, but within these large units the most effective authority was
generally held by the local magnates—the landgrafs, beys, szlachta, and
boyars. The average inhabitant owed indirect allegiance to a distant
emperor or king who had no personal control over him, and direct allegiance to
an aristocratic landlord whose power was real but petty. No central or eastern
European prince could match Philip II or Elizabeth I in sovereign strength.
That is, no eastern European prince could expect several million reasonably
cooperative subjects (like those in Castile and England) to pay burdensome
taxes, obey complex instructions, perform patriotic military service, and
participate intelligently in civil obligations. Only Gustavus Adolphus could
muster from his people the kind of strong community spirit which animated the
Spanish, English, Dutch, and French. Community spirit or national consciousness
was hard to achieve in central and eastern Europe, for the population was
ethnically diverse. Some fourteen major languages were spoken, as against five
in western Europe, and most of the ethnic groups were intermingled. Every large
eastern state was multilingual. The Holy Roman Empire alone included eight
rival ethnic groups. Ethnic rivalries cut across religious rivalries.
Protestants and Catholics staged their family quarrel hemmed in by alien
creeds—Islam and Greek Orthodoxy south of the Danube, and Russian Orthodoxy
east of the Dnieper.
Between 1559 and 1648, during the era of
the religious wars, the disparity between eastern and western Europe widened
steadily. In the mid-sixteenth century this disparity had been disguised by the
immense size of Charles V’s empire, straddling Spain and Germany. The division
of Charles’s empire in 1556 into Spanish and German sections symbolized the new
era. In the west, as we have seen, the religious crisis stimulated the
evolution of an articulate urban capitalist class, as well as the development
of national spirit and of a genuine state sovereignty. In the east the effect
was almost the opposite. Political organization was splintered more than ever,
commerce stagnated, and only the semifeudal class of agricultural magnates
emerged as the true victor. The gains of these local landlords were made at the
expense of the emperors and kings above them and of the burghers and peasants
below. By the close of the seventeenth century, the largest central and eastern
units— the Holy Roman Empire, the Ottoman Empire, the kingdom of Poland —were
in obvious decline. New power centers—the Austrian, Russian, and Prussian
monarchies—were rising. But they were as yet far inferior to France and England
in strength, wealth, and cultural vitality. In short, the religious wars
accelerated the political disintegration of central and eastern Europe at the
very time when the Atlantic states were consolidating their sovereign national
power.
THE HOLY ROMAN EMPIRE, 1555-1618
When Charles V divided his Habsburg empire
in 1556 between his son Philip and his brother Ferdinand, he arranged
Ferdinand’s election as Holy Roman emperor and gave him the family lands (known
collectively as the Austrian Habsburg lands) within the southern and eastern
borders of the empire: the Tyrol, Carinthia, Carniola, Styria, Austria,
Bohemia, Moravia and Silesia, as well as Hungary and other territories beyond
the eastern imperial border. Theoretically, Emperor Ferdinand was a very strong
prince. His was an empire with a population of twenty-five million, three times
the population of Philip II’s Spain. Actually, his power was severely limited.
The Holy Roman Empire was divided into three hundred autonomous political
units, of which at least three dozen had some importance. The real rulers of
Germany were the local princes. During the late sixteenth century the Habsburg
emperors were only nominally in charge of the Holy Roman Empire. They were only
barely able to govern their own family lands and played a far more passive role
in international politics tlian did their Spanish cousins. However, they were
spared the religious warfare which engulfed western Europe; the Religious Peace
of Augsburg, which Ferdinand negotiated with the German princes in 1 555, preserved
an uneasy truce between German Protestants and Catholics until 1618. Peace
allegedly breeds prosperity, but the late sixteenth century was a period of
stagnation not only for the German Habsburgs but for their subjects within the
Holy Roman Empire.
The Peace of Augsburg confirmed the
sovereign authority of the local princes within the empire, its guiding
principle being cuius regio, eius religio (“he who rules a territory
determines its religion”). Catholic princes were permitted to impose Catholicism
upon all their subjects, and Lutheran princes to impose Lutheranism. This
recognition of territorial churches within the empire was a religious
compromise, but not a political one. The German princes, Catholic and Lutheran,
had in effect ganged up against the Habsburgs. They had observed, correctly
enough, that Charles V had been trying not only to crush Protestantism but to
increase Habsburg power and check the centrifugal tendencies within the empire.
They had noticed how he confiscated Lutheran princely territory much more
readily than he enlarged Catholic princely territory, and how he showed real
favor only to members of his own family. The princes, both Lutheran and
Catholic, had also been trying to turn the Reformation crisis to their personal
advantage, by asserting new authority over their local churches, tightening
ecclesiastical patronage, and squeezing more profit from church revenues. In
1552-1553 the Lutheran princes, allied with Henry II of France, had beaten the
imperial forces while the Catholic princes stood by, neutral. The Habsburgs
were forced to accept the Peace of Augsburg, which effectively squelched any
hopes for a German state with a single religion and administration.
As a device for pacifying
Protestant-Catholic strife, the Peace of Augsburg was closer in spirit to Henry
IV’s Edict of Nantes in France than to Elizabeth I’s religious settlement in
England. The Augsburg negotiators refused to let Catholics and Lutherans live
together, except in those German cities where the population already included
members of both groups. The sharp delineation of the two competing confessions
was in strong contrast to the deliberately amorphous character of the Anglican
establishment. Calvinists, Zwinglians, and Anabaptists were not recognized,
though a good many Germans belonged to these churches. In 1555, a
large majority of the German population was Protestant, but the ruling Habsburg
dynasty and four of the seven electors who chose each new emperor were
Catholic. T he old religion was largely confined to the western German
Rhineland and to such south German states as Bavaria. Protestants controlled
almost all of northern and central Germany, and Wiirttemberg, Ansbach, and the
Pa latinate in the south. Even within the Habsburg family lands, Protestantism
was very strong. Most Bohemians and Moravians were Protestants, as were the
nobility and burghers in Austria. How long this prccaiious Protestant-Catholic
balance would last depended very much on the princes.
The German peasantry and urban working
class, scarred by memories of the debacle of the peasants’ revolt in 1524-1526,
were inclined to follow orders inertly on the religious issue, and switch from
Lutheran to Catholic, or vice versa, as their masters required.
The emperors Ferdinand I (ruled
1556-1564), Maximilian II (ruled 1564-1576), Rudolf II (ruled 1576-1612), and
Matthias (ruled 1612-1619) were all far less energetic men than Charles V or
Philip II. Their highest aim was to hold off the Turks in Hungary and to
administer their family holdings along the Danube. These Austrian Habsburg
territories look compactly organized on the map, but they were split into a
dozen distinct governments, and incorporated almost as many language groups.
The greatest source of internal friction W'as religion. During the late
sixteenth century, the Habsburg emperors’ treatment of the Protestants within
their Danubian lands was very gingerly, compared with Philip II’s treatment of
his Protestant subjects in the Netherlands. Only Rudolf II made much effort to
enforce the Augsburg formula: in the Tyrol, Carinthia, Carniola, and Styria, he
managed to convert or deport practically all the Protestants. Some ten thousand
emigrants fled from these provinces between 1598 and 1605. In Austria the task
was more difficult, because the nobility and townspeople were mainly
Protestant. To enforce the Trentine reform decrees, Rudolf II appointed a
Jesuit bishop of Vienna and expelled all Protestant preachers from the city. He
could not cow the Protestant nobility and burghers, however, nor the Austrian
diet or assembly. The Austrian Protestants lost some strength, but in 1609 the
diet extracted a pledge guaranteeing considerable liberty of worship.
In Bohemia, the Habsburgs faced even
stronger opposition. The kingdom of Bohemia was the most populous, prosperous,
and cultivated possession of the Austrian Habsburgs, and like the Netherlands
for the Spanish Habsburgs, the most troublesome. The Czech people were proudly
Slav and overwhelmingly Protestant. They boasted two entrenched native strains
of evangelical Protestantism, the Utraquists (analogous to Lutherans) and the
Bohemian Brethren (somewhat analogous to Calvinists), both stemming back to the
Hussite movement of the early fifteenth century and hence quite separate from
the sixteenth-century Reformation. For two hundred years the Czechs had
stubbornly maintained their independence from Catholic orthodoxy and German
culture. Rudolf II was hardly the man to bring them into line. Melancholic and
unbalanced, the king-emperor sequestered himself in the Hradschin castle in
Prague, enveloped by his art collection, dabbling in science and magic.
Intermittently, he tried to restore Catholicism in Bohemia by appointing
Catholic officials, encouraging Jesuit missionary work among the Utraquists,
and issuing edicts against the Brethren. But in 1609 the Bohemian diet rose up
in rebellion. In order to conciliate the rebels, Rudolf granted his Letter of
Majesty, the fullest guarantee of religious freedom to be found anywhere on the
continent. Obviously the Habsburgs had not yet accomplished much in Bohemia.
In the German heart of the Holy Roman
Empire, the late sixteenth century was a time of prolonged economic depression.
The Hanseatic League of north German cities, which had once dominated commerce
in the Baltic and North seas, was quite unable to compete against Dutch,
Danish, and English merchants. The old overland route to Italy had lost its
central importance. In southwestern Germany, where the cities had been
especially wealthy and enterprising in the fifteenth and early sixteenth
centuries, political fragmentation was most extreme, and the economy suffered
as a result. Each prince, striving for sovereign power within his petty state,
levied taxes and tolls which clogged commerce and reduced manufacturing output.
The Fuggers of Augsburg, the leading bankers in Europe in the mid- sixteenth
century, with control of Tyrolese silver and Hungarian copper production,
overstrained themselves with loans to the Habsburgs toward the end of the
century, and their business empire rapidly fell apart. As the Fuggers and the
other leading German entrepreneurs lost their wealth and the German cities
declined in population, the princes dominated the scene more than ever.
The princes, both Protestant and Catholic,
were growing dissatisfied with the religious truce they had worked out in 1555.
One source of trouble was Calvinist expansion. In 1559 Elector Frederick III of
the Palatinate (1515-1576) had introduced a modified version of
Calvin’s church organization into his central Rhineland territory. The
elector’s fellow princes, Catholic and Lutheran, vainly protested this clear
violation of the Augsburg treaty. Heidelberg, the Palatine capital, became the
Geneva of Germany. Scholars at the university formulated the Heidelberg
Catechism in 1563 as a creed for the German Reformed (or Calvinist) churches.
Within a generation the princes of Nassau, Hesse, and Anhalt had swung their
central German states from Lutheranism to the German Reformed church. In 1613
the elector of Brandenburg announced his conversion also, though he abandoned
the cuius regio, eius religio formula of Augsburg by letting his
Lutheran subjects retain their religion. Two of the three Protestant imperial
electors were now Calvinists; only the elector of Saxony remained Lutheran. The German Reformed princes acted more aggressively than their Lutheran
colleagues, because they were not included in the Lutheran-Catholic compromise
of 1 555. Frederick III and his Palatine successors assumed leadership of the
Protestant cause within the empire, and finding the other German Protestant
princes to be torpid or hostile, looked abroad to the French Huguenots and
Dutch Calvinists for help in times of crisis. Yet the German Reformed church
lacked dynamism. Unlike the Calvinism of western Europe it was not a
spontaneous force among German merchants and gentry; it depended upon princely
sponsors and was state controlled. Its growth was strictly limited. Although it
made inroads into Lutheranism, it had little impact among Catholics, and it
could not by itself re-ignite religious warfare.
A second, and more important, source of
rising tension was the spread of the Catholic reformation within the empire.
The south German state of Bavaria became the nucleus of renewed Catholic zeal
and political power. Duke Albert V of Bavaria (ruled 1550-1579)
enthusiastically enforced the reform decrees of the Council of Trent. He
stamped out all traces of Protestant heresy by having his ecclesiastical agents
inspect every Bavarian church annually, revamp the schools systematically, and
censor all books. Jesuits were invited to take charge of the Bavarian schools
and universities, and the duke’s subjects were forbidden to study abroad. The
new style of dogmatic Catholicism facilitated political autocracy in Bavaria.
When Protestant nobles and burghers tried to protest, Albert excluded them
from the Bavarian diet, thereby effectively emasculating that assembly. By the
close of the sixteenth century, the duke of Bavaria was governing in a more
absolute fashion than any other German prince.
Elsewhere in Germany, the Catholics began
to win back converts. Between 1580 and 1610, Protestants were driven out of a
whole series of cities, among them Cologne, Aachen, Strasbourg, Wiirzberg,
Bamberg, Munster, Paderborn, and Osnabriick. Everywhere, the Jesuits were in
the forefront of the campaign. They established schools and universities in key
German cities and made a specialty of educating young Catholic princes. Peter
Canisius (1521-1597) is the best known of these sixteenth-century German Jesuit
missionaries. The striking Jesuit Michaelskirche (Church of St. Michael) in
Munich, built by the dukes of Bavaria, is a symbol of the Catholic reformation.
This church was erected in the 1580’s, when St. Peter’s was nearing completion
in Rome, and it introduced to Germany the sumptuous classical architecture of
the reformed papacy. The Munich tourist today need only visit two churches a
block apart, built a century apart—the fifteenth-century Frauenkirche (Church
of Our Lady) and the sixteenth-century Michaels kirche—to catch the immense
psychological distance between pre- and post-reformation German Catholicism.
The Gothic Frauenkirche rises in awkward vertical bulk, austere and homely, her
round capped towers reflect ing the native Bavarian style, and her soaring nave
expressing a quest inr. spirit. By contrast, the Michaelskirche is
international in style, harmonious in scale and proportion, and lavishly decorated
to proclaim the certitude, symmetry, and power of the new Church Militant.
By 1609 all signs pointed to the end of
the Augsburg truce. The imperial Diet, the one vestige of collective German
government, collapsed in 1608 when the Protestant representatives boycotted its
proceedings. In 1609 the most aggressive German Protestant states formed a
Protestant Union for self-defense, headed by the Elector Palatine, whereupon
the most aggressive Catholic states immediately formed a rival Catholic League,
headed by the duke of Bavaria. Yet it must be emphasized that the German
princes in their two armed camps still dreaded Armageddon. The Protestant Union
was ineffectual because the Lutheran elector of Saxony would not ally himself
with the Calvinist Elector Palatine. Nor was the Catholic League much stronger,
thanks to hostility between the Austrian Habsburgs and the Bavarian
Wittelsbachs. Both sides had pretext for war in 1609 when two Rhenish
principalities, Jiilich and Cleve, were contested by rival Protestant and
Catholic claimants. Eventually, in 1614, a compromise was worked out by which
Jiilich went to the Catholic claimant and Cleve to the Protestant. But when the
next crisis came in Bohemia in 1618, it could not be patched up.
The problems of these years become easier
to visualize if we think of the Holy Roman Empire as being something like the
mid-twentieth-century world in microcosm. The inhabitants of the empire were
culture-bound to their own cities or provinces as modern man is culture-bound
to his own nation. People refused to admit, then as now, that their fate
depended upon cooperation with strangers who spoke and thought differently, but
lived uncomfortably close by. Politicians waged ideological cold war, their
motivation ostensibly religious instead of political or economic. Protestant
and Catholic imperial states formed alliance systems to maintain the balance of
power. Whenever a Lutheran prince converted to Catholicism or vice versa,
diplomacy was required to keep the conflict local. When delegates from the
various states convened in the imperial Diet, the only institution effectively
embracing their whole community, they raised issues without attempting to solve
them, just as the members of the United Nations do today. Gradually even this meager
spirit of imperial community disappeared. The cold war grew inexorably warmer.
Leaders on both sides, sick of the stalemate, began supposing that they could
solve issues simply by unilateral action. And when they did take unilateral
action, in 1618, they plunged the empire into thirty years of civil war.
EASTERN BORDERLANDS: THE OTTOMAN EMPIRE, POLAND, RUSSIA, AND SWEDEN
To the east of the Holy Roman Empire, in
the late sixteenth century, three extremely large states filled the map—the
Ottoman Empire, Poland, and Russia. North of the Baltic Sea lay the extensive
kingdom of Sweden. These states, particularly the Ottoman Empire and Muscovite
Russia, seemed profoundly alien to western and central Europeans. Travelers
found the Turks and Russians almost as barbaric and exotic as the Indians of
America, and infinitely more dangerous because of their large armies, equipped
with modern weapons. English merchants, venturing to trade with the Turks and
Russians in the late sixteenth century, wrote home to describe the amazing
Mohammedan and Greek Orthodox religious practices they had witnessed, the
bizarre architecture, food, and dress, the stark contrast between an opulent
ruling caste and an impoverished peasantry, the vast extent of these eastern
lands and the herculean scale of their armies. “We arrived at the great and
most stately city of Constantinople,” one traveler reported, “which for the
situation and proud seat thereof, for the beautiful and commodious haven, for
the great and sumptuous buildings of their Temples, which they call Mosques, is
to be preferred before all the cities of Europe. And there the Emperor of the
Turks kept his Court and residence, at least two miles in compass.” Yet no
westerner forgot that the Turks were infidels. Their lavish oriental ceremonies
seemed tedious and empty. Their eunuchs and seraglios evoked incredulous
contempt. Turkish warriors had an unrivaled reputation for cruelty and deceit.
As for Muscovy, the few westerners who
penetrated into this land told tales of a climate too extreme for civilized man
to endure. In the sub-zero Russian winter, “you shall see many drop down in the
streets, many travelers brought into the towns sitting stiff and dead in their
sleds. The bears and wolves issue by troops out of the woods driven by hunger,
and enter the villages, tearing and ravening all they can find.” The Russians,
it was said, besot themselves with kvass and mead. They had strange smoky
complexions because they took too many steam baths. Their primitive wooden
buildings were constantly burning down. When the invading Tartars set fire to
Moscow in 1571, they largely wiped out Russia’s chief city within four hours.
The Muscovite tsar, for all his jewels and ornate skirted garments and his
giant feasts on plates of gold, seemed semicivilized at best. An English poet
who visited Moscow in 1568 summed up in jogging verse the westerner’s easy
disdain for these eastern borderlands of European civilization:
The cold is rare, the people rude, the
prince so full of pride,
The realm so stored with monks and nuns,
and priests on every side,
The manners are so Turkey like, the men so
full of guile,
The women wanton, Temples stuft with idols
that defile The seats that sacred ought to be, the customs are so quaint,
As if I would describe the whole, I fear
my pen would faint.
Wild Irish are as civil as the Russies in
their kind,
Hard choice which is the best of both,
each bloody, rude and blind.
Fortunately for the west, the Turks,
Poles, and Russians were all politically weak in the late sixteenth and early
seventeenth centuries. Size was deceptive in these sprawling eastern states.
The Turkish sultan, the Polish king, and the Muscovite tsar were all less
effectual rulers than western observers supposed. Their armies were much
smaller than westerners thought them to be, and in any case generally faced
east in order to cope with the Persians and Tartars. Hence, despite the near
paralysis of the Holy Roman Empire, its eastern neighbors did not intervene
effectively in German affairs between 1 555 and 1618. Nor (except for Sweden)
did they participate in the Thirty Years’ War. How is this uniform political
softness in eastern Europe to be explained?
The Ottoman Empire
The Ottoman Empire had been anything but
soft before the middle of the sixteenth century. Suleiman the Magnificent
(ruled 1520-1566), the Iasi of the great Turkish warrior sultans, held the
whole Balkan peninsula and most of Hungary. He had thirty million subjects, a
revenue greater than that of Charles V, and a much more efficient military
system, including i permanent standing army of over ten thousand infantry
(janissaiics), over ten thousand cavalry
(spahis), and at least a hundred thousand auxiliary cavalry available for
annual campaigns. The janissaries were Moslem converts, mainly drawn from the
conquered Greek Orthodox peoples of the Balkans. Taken captive as boys by the
sultan’s forces, they were rigorously trained to fight for Islam and to
administer the Ottoman Empire. They formed an enslaved elite, permanently
dependent on the sultan, given a professional schooling, never allowed to marry
or to inherit lands and titles, yet freely promoted on the basis of talent and
merit to the highest imperial posts. They made superb soldiers.
After the death of Suleiman the
Magnificent, the Turkish fighting machine lost much of its fearsome power and
its expansive drive. In 1571 the Spanish Habsburgs smashed the Turkish fleet at
Lepanto. In the 1590’s the Austrian Habsburgs tried to capture Hungary and
Transylvania, and did keep the Ottoman armies mostly on the defensive, though
the peace terms of 1606 left the Balkan frontier unchanged. Ottoman passivity
gave the Habsburgs freedom to concentrate on German affairs after 1618, and
when the Thirty Years’ War went badly for the Habsburgs, the Turks failed to
capitalize on a golden opportunity for further western expansion.
The key to Turkish success had always been
strong military leadership by the sultan. After Suleiman came a long line of
feckless sultans who abandoned Mars for Venus. They ceased to conduct military
campaigns, ceased even to emerge from the Constantinople harem. Back in the
days of tough, ruthless leadership, each new Ottoman sultan had stabilized his
accession by killing his younger brothers (they were strangled with a silken
bowstring so as not to shed exalted blood). Now, with the sultans’ amorous
proclivities resulting in numerous progeny, this custom was turning the
seraglio into a slaughterhouse. In 1595 the new sultan had forty-six brothers
and sisters, and he thought it necessary to strangle his nineteen brothers and
fifteen pregnant harem women. In the seventeenth century this systematic
fratricide was stopped, but by then the sultan himself had become a puppet,
frequently deposed in palace revolutions. With no new lands to conquer and
little war booty to enjoy, the Turkish soldiery became preoccupied with status
and intrigue. The janissaries changed radically, becoming in the seventeenth
century a closed, self-perpetuating caste. They now married, passed their jobs on
to their sons, agitated for new perquisites, and engineered palace coups. As
the economy stagnated and tax levies dwindled, bribery and corruption greatly
increased.
In the 1650’s, a drastic administrative
shake-up in Constantinople temporarily revived the old militancy and
efficiency. In the 1660’s the Turks captured the island of Crete from Venice.
They tightened their grip over Hungary and resumed their drive up the Danube
into Austria. In 1683 they laid siege to Vienna. But in the closing decades of
the seventeenth century, Ottoman expansion was once again stopped, this time
decisively. The Turks were forced to surrender Hungary in 1699, and their huge
empire began to shrink. This shrinkage continued for nearly 250 years. In the
early nineteenth century the Turks still held half of Suleiman’s European
territory and all of his North African and Near Eastern possessions. The First
World War marked the final stage: the Turks were confined at last to Anatolia,
and the Ottoman Empire was dissolved. Seldom, if ever, has a decaying state
disintegrated so slowly. In the seventeenth century, the Ottoman Empire had by
no means yet become the Sick Man of Europe. Buttressed by total intellectual
isolation from the new currents in European culture, the Turks still retained
their profound contempt for the West. “Do I not know,” the grand vizier told
the French ambassador in 1666, “that you are a Giaour [nonbeliever], that you
are a hog, a dog, a turd eater?”
Ottoman Europe—that is, the Balkan
peninsula—was something of a cultural no-man’s-land in the sixteenth and
seventeenth centuries: only superficially Turkish, cut off from Latin
Christendom, and with a very rudimentary native peasant style of life. The
Turks had wiped out the native ruling class when they conquered the Balkans,
but they never migrated into the area in large numbers, nor did they try to
assimilate the local peasantry, which they preferred to keep as permanently
unprivileged agricultural laborers. From the Turkish viewpoint, the Balkan
peasants were fairly easy to subjugate as long as they remained divided into
six rival language groups: Greeks, Albanians, Bulgarians, Serbo-Croatians,
Rumanians, and Magyars.
Instead of imposing Mohammedanism upon the
subject peoples, the Turks encouraged the perpetuation of the Greek Orthodox
Church, largely to keep the Balkan population hostile to western Christianity.
This Ottoman policy did indeed effectively curb Balkan defection to the
Catholic Habsburgs or Poles. The Orthodox patriarch in Constantinople repaid
his Turkish patrons by teaching his people to submit docilely to Ottoman rule.
Certainly the Ottoman Empire was more tolerant of all sorts of alien cultures
and customs than any contemporaneous state in western Europe. French, English,
and Dutch merchants were granted their own trading enclaves in Turkey, governed
by western law. Jews flocked from Spain to enjoy Turkish freedom. The few towns
in the Balkans were inhabited mainly by Turks and Jews; minarets and bazaars
gave these towns an oriental atmosphere. In the Balkan countryside, the
Christian peasants were confined to the lowest rung of the Ottoman social
ladder; illiterate, ignorant, and silent, they paid extortionate taxes and
tributes. In the sixteenth century their young sons were frequently levied as
janissaries, and in the seventeenth century their farms were often pillaged by
brigands. Even so, they probably fared no worse than any other peasants in
eastern Europe.
Poland
North of the Ottoman Empire and cast of
the Holy Roman Empire lay the extensive kingdom of Poland, stretching from the
Oder to the Dnieper River and from the Baltic almost to the Black Sea. Poland
had no natural frontiers except for the Baltic coast to the north and the
Carpathian Mountains to the south. Its six million widely scattered inhabitants
raised grain and cattle. In the eastern part of the kingdom agricultural
development was hindered by the attacks of wild Cossack raiders and by vast
stretches of marshland. Cracow and Danzig, both on the western border, were the
two chief towns. Poland did possess considerable human and natural resources,
yet in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries it played only a feeble
international role, and in the eighteenth century the Polish state completely
disappeared. There were ethnic and religious reasons for Poland’s failure, but
by far the biggest problem was political disorganization.
The dominant Polish social class was the szlaclita,
the landed gentry. Its members—like twelfth-century feudal knights in the
west—were absolute masters of their rural domains; they forced the peasantry
into serfdom, extracted unpaid labor from the serfs, disdained the burghers who
huddled behind the town walls, and frustrated every effort by the Polish kings
to consolidate power. The szlachta formed a numerous class—8 per cent of
the total population. A typical sixteenth-century Polish landlord owned a
village and its surrounding grain fields. His serfs labored for him two or
three days a week, and loaded his harvested grain into river barges to be shipped
to the Baltic for export west. He tried and punished his serfs in his own
court, without fear of appeal to the king, for the szlachta had virtual
immunity from arrest and trial. The landlord paid few taxes, saw occasional
military service, sat in the local seym, or diet, sent delegates to the
national Diet, and helped to elect the king. Poland was called a royal republic
because the gentry voted their king into office and handcuffed him with
constitutional limitations. It is said that fifty thousand szlachta assembled
at Warsaw in 1573 to elect asking the French prince Henry of Valois—this was an
unusually bad choice, and the Poles were lucky that he skipped the country
after six months in order to take the French throne as Henry III (see p. 36).
The Polish gentry were so suspicious of dynastic power that they almost always
elected foreigners. Between 1548 and 1668 the winning candidates were
Lithuanian, French, Hungarian, and Swedish. These kings lacked the royal lands,
budget, army, and bureaucracy of western monarchs. The Polish serfs had less
individual freedom than the Balkan peasantry under Turkish rule. When romantic
Polish historians talk of their country’s sixteenth-century “gentry democracy,”
one should remember that they are using a pretty special definition of
democracy.
Like other eastern European states, Poland
was ethnically divided, a situation which compounded its political
difficulties. Poles occupied the west, Lithuanians the northeast, White
Russians the east, and Ruthenians the south, and Germans and Jews congregated
in the towns. Of all these peoples, only Poles and Lithuanians were admitted
to the ruling landlord class. Since 1386, the members of the Lithuanian
nobility had shared a common king with the Polish gentry but in most ways had
run their own affairs. In 1569 the Lithuanian nobility became so frightened by
Tsar Ivan the Terrible of Russia that they surrendered their autonomy and in
the Union of Lublin merged with the Polish ruling caste. Henceforth the
Polish-Lithuanian landlords had a single king, a single Diet (meeting at
Warsaw, near the Polish-Lithuanian border), and a single foreign policy. But
the union was always superficial, for the Lithuanians continued to manage their
White Russian peasants in their own fashion and kept their own laws and
language. Indeed, each ethnic group had its own language. Since the szlachta
sneered at the Polish dialect spoken by their serfs, they adopted Latin as the
religious, political, and literary language of the ruling class. The szlachta
sneered also at the German-speaking townspeople, who were excluded from the
Diet and from political power. The Yiddish-speaking Jewish community was
despised by everyone.
The Christians in Poland were doubly
divided in the mid-sixteenth century. The people were predominantly Latin
Christians, except in the south and east, where they were largely Greek
Orthodox; this division was only papered over in 1596, when the Ruthenian
Orthodox church agreed to obey the pope and accept the Roman dogma while retaining
its Slavonic rites and practices. The second religious division was among Latin
Chris tians—Catholic versus Protestant. In the 1550’s, Polish Catholics found
themselves in a very precarious majority, for about half the szlachta
were Calvinist, and the German burghers were largely Lutheran. Even Unitarian,
or anti-Trinitarian, ideas were circulating, possibly inspired by contact with
Jewish and Moslem teachings. In 1555 King Sigismund Augustus (ruled 1548-1572)
and the Polish Diet agreed to allow individual freedom of worship to
Protestants. The heresy-hunting power of Catholic church courts was suspended.
More than the contemporaneous Augsburg formula in Germany, this Polish policy
weakened ecclesiastical discipline and sapped what little cultural unity there
was. But the Protestant Reformation was not well rooted in Poland. The szlachta
had adopted Calvinism as a weapon against centralized monarchy, and once
assured of political victory, they lost interest in the new doctrine. During
the late sixteenth century the Catholics—their efforts spearheaded by Jesuit
upper-class missionary work— regained control. Numerous Jesuit schools were
opened for the sons of the gentry. By the mid-seventeenth century, with
Catholicism securely reestablished, education stagnated even for the upper
class. Proud and touchy, the Polish gentry cultivated long mustachios and
oriental sashed costumes as their badge of immunity from Italian or French
standards of civility. Poland in the seventeenth century became almost as isolated
as Ottoman Turkey from the intellectual currents of western Europe.
Between 1559 and 1715, Poland faced east
and north rather than west in all its wars and diplomacy. It fought the Turks
intermittently without permanently winning or losing any territory. It fought
the Swedes constantly and generally got beaten. In 1629 it ceded the province
of Livonia to Sweden, and had to accept Swedish control of the Baltic. Poland’s
most menacing neighbor was Russia, and the Poles were lucky that internal
Muscovite turmoil in the late sixteenth and early seventeenth centuries delayed
effective Russian westward expansion. In 1667 Poland ceded Smolensk, Kiev, and
the eastern Ukraine to Russia.
These sizable territorial losses were less
alarming than Poland’s rising political anarchy, which paralyzed the state and
invited further foreign encroachment. The gentry were so suspicious of
centralized royal power that in the Diet legislation could not pass without the
unanimous consent of the szlachta deputies. In the sixteenth century the
majority of deputies could generally persuade or coerce the minority into
accepting a policy. But in 1652, for the first time, an individual deputy
declared his total opposition, his liberum veto against the legislative
proceedings, and left the chamber— forcing the Diet to disband. Henceforth, 90
percent of the Polish Diets were “exploded” in this way, by use of the
individual liberum veto. It became possible for the French, Prussians,
or other foreign powers, by bribing refractory members of the gentry, to veto
Polish tax laws or stymie Polish military preparations. To many observers,
Poland’s “gentry democracy” proved the folly of constitutional self-government
'and the necessity for absolute monarchy. To the Russians, Prussians, and
Austrians, Poland’s governmental paralysis offered an excellent excuse for
partitioning the state in the eighteenth century.
Russia
East of Poland lay the vast tsardom of
Muscovy, or Russia. In the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries it was an open
question whether Russia was part of European civilization, for in scale and
temper, life there differed profoundly from life in the rest of Europe. To
begin with, the country was gigantic. In 1533, when Ivan the Terrible inherited
the throne, Muscovy stretched 1,200 miles, from Smolensk to the Ural Mountains,
and covered five times the area of France. Ivan nearly doubled his European
holdings by annexing the Don and Volga river basins to the south, and launched
the Russian eastward trek across the Urals into Siberia. By the time Peter the
Great became tsar in 1682, the Russians had annexed further European land along
the Dnieper and Ural rivers, and their Asian settlements were strung along the
Siberian river system for five thousand miles, right to the Pacific. Russia
then covered thirty times the area of France.
The climate throughout this continental
sweep of territory was savage by European standards, with arctic winters, blazing
summers, and a short growing season. Population estimates for sixteenth- and
seventeenth-century Russia are pure guesswork, but whether one accepts the
lowest, four million inhabitants, or the highest, seventeen million, it is
evident that settlement was far less dense than in western and central Europe.
The huge reservoir of empty land encouraged hit-and-run agricultural
techniques. The peasants were extremely mobile, sometimes voluntarily migrating
long distances to find better land and working conditions, sometimes forcibly
transported by their landlords or the tsar. In contrast with western Europe,
where people habitually tilled the same ancestral land, lived in the same
village, and even occupied the same buildings for centuries, no human enterprise
seemed lasting in Russia. The average wooden peasant’s hut was built to last
four years. An English traveler between Yaroslavl and Moscow in 1553 was
impressed by the numerous villages he passed through; thirty-five years later
another English visitor found the same region deserted and gone back to forest.
Tartar raiders periodically swept into Muscovy from the Crimea, as Viking,
Saracen, and Magyar raiders had pillaged western and central Europe in the
ninth century. The Tartars carried hundreds of thousands of Russians off into
slavery. Belief in the individual dignity of man—fragile enough in the
sixteenth-century west—was an unobtainable luxury for Muscovites. Tsars,
nobles, priests, and peasants all accepted physical brutality—flogging and
torture—as staple features of society.
Russia’s contact with western Europe was
minimal between 1559 and 1682. Blocked by Sweden from an outlet on the Baltic
during most of these years, and by Turkey from an outlet on the Black Sea,
Russia had only one port—Archangel, on the White Sea—from which to trade
directly with western Europe. Its commerce with the Middle East was more
important Strange as it seems, western Europeans had built closer commercial
and diplomatic contact with Russia in the eleventh and twelfth centuries than they
did in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. The Muscovites found it far
easier to spread eastward into empty Siberia than to reconquer from Poland the
White Russian and Ukrainian lands which had oncc belonged to their ancestors.
Not until the reign of Peter the Great did the Russians learn how to beat a
crack European army.
P.ussia’s most meaningful tie with the
west was Christianity. Yet the Russian Orthodox clergy viewed Latin Christendom
with the darkest suspicion. For centuries they had accepted as spiritual
overlord the Greek Orthodox patriarch at Constantinople, and when Byzantium
fell to the Ottomans, the Russian Orthodox naturally supposed that the
metropolitan of Moscow' had inherited the role of the patriarch of Constantinople
as the leader of true Christianity. In 1588 the patriarch of Constantinople
grudgingly accepted the metropolitan’s elevation to patriarch of Moscow. The
Russians called Moscow the third Rome. They believed that Old Rome had fallen
into heresy under the popes, and that New Rome (Constantinople) had become a
pawn of the infidel Turks; Moscow was the third and greatest capital of the
Christian world. Because of their hostility to the papacy, the Muscovites were
better disposed toward Protestant merchants and diplomats from England, the
Netherlands, Scandinavia, and Germany than toward Catholics. But the Russians
wanted no Reformation in their own church, nor even any discussion over the
smallest details of Orthodox belief and practice.
The Russians settled Tobolsk, beyond the
Urals, in 1587, two years after Sir Walter Raleigh first tried to found an
English plantation at Roanoke Island, North Carolina. The Russians reached the
Pacific in 1643, a few years after the English Puritans had founded
Massachusetts. It would be hard to find a stronger social contrast than that
between the Russian folk movement across Eurasia and the contemporaneous
English folk movement into North America. Both peoples held an enormous
reservoir of empty land, but while the Americans methodically inched their way
inland, taking nearly three centuries to span the continent, the Russians
lightly spanned Siberia in two generations. Frontier America was a paradise for
the self-reliant, egalitarian free farmer, disdainful of government, unencumbered
by taxes. But in Russia, frontier expansion fostered the sharpest possible
social stratification, and Europe’s most autocratic, oppressive government. The
members of the Muscovite nobility, who held great estates in European Russia,
were determined not to let their agricultural laborers move off to free land
in Siberia. So they introduced new regulations which tied the laborer and his
descendants to his master’s soil or (better yet) to his master’s person—in
short, turned the peasant into a serf, virtually indistinguishable from a
slave. At the same time, the tsars were determined not to let their nobility
carve up the land into autonomous feudal principalities, or perpetrate
political anarchy in the fashion of the Polish szlachta. So they ruthlessly
killed all aristocratic troublemakers, confiscated their large properties, and
divided them into smaller parcels suitable for the pomeshchik, a loyal
dependent employed in the royal army or administration. Since the members of
this service nobility could not own land outright, but held it from the tsar
only as long as they served him, they tended to squeeze the peasants hard in
order to make short-run profits. Peasants ran away from pomeshchik
estates with special frequency. By the seventeenth century, the landlords and
the tsar had reached a tacit understanding. The landlords accepted the
principle that they must serve the tsar, and in return the tsar agreed that the
peasants—90 per cent of the population—were legally defined as serfs, bound to
their master and subject to his will.
Ivan IV (ruled 1533-1584), better known as
Ivan the Terrible, was the principal author of the Muscovite formula: absolute
power for the tsar, state service for the nobility, thralldom for the
peasantry. Far less evidence has survived about the details of Ivan’s reign
than about the reigns of his western contemporaries, Philip II and Elizabeth I,
but we know enough to tell that his style of rule differed utterly from theirs.
As a young prince, Ivan amused himself by tossing animals from the palace tower
and watched them die in agony. In 1547 he had himself crowned Tsar (that is,
“Caesar”) of All the Russians, the first Muscovite ruler to do so. His behavior
toward his subjects could be described as mad in a half dozen distinct
senses—raging, frantic, foolish, visionary, giddy, lunatic. He decimated the boyar
class, the hereditary Russian aristocracy, by killing hundreds, probably even
thousands, of its members. He pitilessly sacked Novgorod, the second city in
his realm, because of a rumor of disloyalty.
His deep piety did not prevent him from
flogging and torturing priests or killing his victims in church during Mass. He
once had an archbishop sewn into a bearskin and tossed to the dogs. He struck
his oldest son and heir so hard with a pointed stick that he killed him, and it
is supposed that his melancholic brooding over this crime hastened his own
demise. Most of the time there was method in Ivan’s madness. His wholesale
confiscation and redistribution of land was economically catastrophic,
depopulating much of central Russia, but it broke the boyar power and
bolstered that of the new service nobility. The more Ivan bullied the Russian
Orthodox Church, the more the clergy preached abject reverence to God’s
lieutenant, the tsar. Uncivilized Ivan certainly was, but he magnetized the
Russian landlords and peasants alike with his awesome God-given power. The tsar
of Russia had far greater psychological appeal for the mass of the people than
did the elected monarchs of Poland or the seraglio sultans of T urkey.
Ivan the Tcrrible’s successor, Fedor
(ruled 1584-1598), was mad in a less complicated way than his father; he was a
simpleton who chiefly delighted in ringing church bells. Fedor’s reign
inaugurated Muscovy’s “Time of Troubles,” the period of aristocratic rebellion
against tsarist autocracy, which lasted from 1584 to 1613. Among the tsars in
this anarchic period was Boris Godunov (ruled 1598-1605), more famous thanks to
Mussorgsky’s opera than his statecraft deserves. During these years the Russian
landlords tried to run the country as the szlachta ran Poland. A
national assembly, the zemsky sobor, assumed the authority to choose
each new tsar. Marauding armies, led by would-be tsars, ransacked the
countryside. During the Time of Troubles, the church was the one institution
which held Russia together. People gathered in the fortresslike monasteries for
protection, and left their land and wealth to the church. Gradually, the
political role of the clergy became stronger than it had been under Ivan IV.
In 1613, the zemsky sobor chose
Michael Romanov (ruled 1613-1645) as the new tsar because he was a youthful
mediocrity—dubious accreditation for the dynasty which would rule Russia for
the next three hundred years. But this first Romanov had other assets. He was a
grandnephew of Ivan the Terrible, and the son of an able priest-politician
named Philaret, who became patriarch of Moscow soon after Michael ascended the
throne. Philaret made himself the real ruler of Russia, and the patriarchs who
succeeded him after his death in 1633 were equally ambitious for secular power.
The church’s obtrusive political role during this period distressed many
Russian clergy and laity. A crisis developed during the patriarchate of Nikon
(1652-1666), for Nikon not only ruled in the name of the tsar but claimed a
theoretical supremacy over the tsar, since the spiritual realm is higher than
the temporal. Nikon was deposed, and the tsars regained control over the
Russian church. But Nikon’s policies left a bitter legacy. In order to bring Russian
Orthodoxy into closer conformity with Greek Orthodoxy,
Nikon had introduced certain technical
revisions in ecclesiastical practice, such as making the sign of the Cross with
three fingers rather than two, and spelling Christ’s name Iisus rather
than Isus. Many Russians supposed that these innovations blasphemed God
and imperiled their immortal souls. These people, styled the Old Believers,
felt that Nikon had disastrously corrupted the third Rome. We are told that
twenty thousand Old Believers burned themselves alive in despair at the
impending end of the world.
The first Romanov tsars, those ruling
between 1613 and 1682, were much less forceful monarchs than Ivan the Terrible.
But they maintained the partnership with the church and they won the cooperation
of the landlords. The zemsky sobor faded away, though not before it
ratified the final codification of serfdom. The great problem now was how to
stop the serfs from running away. A decree of 1664 required that any serf owner
who was caught receiving a fugitive serf must compensate the master with four
peasant families of his own. Tsar and landlord aided each other in taking away
the peasant’s freedom and in saddling him with taxes. The cost of warfare and
of government-sponsored colonization fell squarely on the people least able to
pay. It is estimated that the peasant tax rate in 1640 was a hundred times what
it had been in 1540!1 In the mid-seventeenth century a major
epidemic drastically depleted the Russian labor force, making the tsar and the landlords
more eager than ever to exact taxes and work from the serfs, and making the
serfs more eager than ever to join the floating population of runaways and
bandits. Many serfs yearned to join the Cossacks on the southern frontier, and
take up a nomadic life as hunters, fishermen, and guerrilla warriors against
the Tartars, Turks, and Persians.
Between 1667 and 1671 Russia was the scene
of the largest European folk rising of the century, a peasant rebellion led by
Stephen Razin in the Volga basin. Razin was a Cossack who had operated as a
river pirate on the Volga and then had sailed into the Caspian Sea to raid the
Persians. Word spread that when he returned with his Persian loot to Astrakhan,
he passed through the bazaars, dressed in oriental magnificence, distributing
silks and jewels among the people. Suddenly he was a liberating folk hero to
the Russian masses, a Robin Hood with the magical powers of the tsar. As
disciples flocked to him, Stephen Razin moved along the Don and the Volga,
proclaiming that he was rescuing the tsar from the wicked boyars so that
all could live in freedom and equality. In villages and towns throughout the
middle Volga region, huge numbers of serfs rose against their lords and formed
into rebel bands. But Razin had no organization, and his followers had no
military discipline. The tsar’s soldiers beat Razin in pitched battle and
chased him into the Don marshes. His magical authority evaporated. He was
captured and executed.
Meanwhile, the tsar and the nobility
smashed one rebel band after another, and terrorized the peasantry into
submission by dismembering the rebels they caught alive, or impaling them on
stakes, or nailing them onto gibbets. Razin’s rebellion accomplished nothing. A
hundred thousand serfs may have died in their vain struggle for liberty. Such
was the starkly stratified and deeply insular society on which Peter the Great
forcibly imposed western technology and cultural mores in the years following
1682.
Sweden
West of Russia and north of Poland lay the
kingdom of Sweden. Seven- teenth-century Sweden was a Baltic empire, double its
twentieth-century size; it incorporated modern Finland, Estonia, and Latvia,
and extensive Russian, Polish, and German coastal land. Sweden held 2,500 miles
of Baltic shoreline. Nonetheless, its resources were puny compared with those
of Turkey, Poland, or Russia. Sweden’s was a simple society of a million or so
peasants, who subsisted on porridge, turnips, coarse bread, and home-brewed
beer. Stockholm was the one town of any size; commerce was mainly conducted by
foreigners; and specie was so scarce that wages, taxes, and debts were paid in
kind. The king of Sweden was the only European monarch who found it necessary
to build warehouses to store his revenue of butter, fish, and hops. Sweden had
always been on Europe’s cultural periphery: it boasted a medieval university,
but the Renaissance had scarcely touched its shores. Swedish political
structure was rudimentary by western standards. Yet Sweden was the only one of
the borderland states to play a vigorous international hand in the years
between 1559 and 1700.
Under the leadership of a young nobleman
named Gustavus Vasa, Sweden had secured independence from Denmark in the early
sixteenth century. Gustavus Vasa established himself as king of Sweden and
ruled purposefully from 1 523 to 1560. But his three sons, who reigned between
1560 and 1611, squabbled among themselves and alienated their subjects. When
sixteen- year-old Gustavus Adolphus inherited the throne in 1611, Sweden was in
acute crisis. It was at war with Denmark, and the war was going so poorly that
the Danes appeared likely to reconquer the country.
Gustavus Adolphus (ruled 1611-1632) shaped
Sweden almost overnight into a major power. He had some good material to work
with. For one thing, the Protestant Reformation had infused the early
seventeenth-century Swedes with crusading ardor. As in England, the Swedish
Reformation had begun in the 1520’s and 15 30’s as a cynical maneuver to grab
Church land and wealth, and only slowly did Luther’s gospel cry stir the
people. By the 1620’s, however, Sweden’s warfare with Catholic Poland and
Orthodox Russia for control of the Baltic was having much the same galvanizing
effect as Elizabethan England’s warfare with Catholic Spain. Calvinism made
small headway in Sweden; the country was solidly Lutheran. Gustavus Adolphus’ clergy were more truculent than their brethren in Germany.
The king’s chaplain dared to reprove him publicly for his sexual laxity, whereupon
Gustavus Adolphus (who deserved this reproof far less than most contemporary
monarchs) gave "the chaplain the next vacant bishopric— surely a
commendable way to avoid hearing further sermons. Another Swedish asset was the
sturdy independence of the peasant farmers. In Sweden, society was not
polarized into a landlord master class and an en- serfed peasantry, as in
Turkey, Poland, and Russia. There were no serfs in Sweden. The peasants owned
50 per cent of the arable land. They had their own chamber in the Riksdag,
or national assembly. The nobility were correspondingly less rich and
privileged than in the great eastern European states. To be sure, they assumed
political leadership, possessed large farms, hired tenant laborers, and
exhibited family pride. But in style of life the Swedish noblemen were none too
distant from the peasants. From this comparatively undifferentiated, homespun,
God-fearing society, Gustavus Adolphus drew a peerless army of self-reliant
soldiers, militant chaplains, and officers eager to invade and plunder Sweden’s
wealthier neighbors.
Gustavus Adolphus is best known as a
warrior, the Protestant hero in the Thirty Years’ War. He began his reign by
making peace with Denmark, but he soon took advantage of the internal weakness
of his neighbors, wresting territory along the Gulf of Finland (the future site
of St. Petersburg) from the Russians and Livonia (modern Latvia) from the
Poles. The tolls he levied upon captured southern Baltic ports enabled him to
finance further military operations without overtaxing the Swedish people.
Swedish copper and iron mines supplied added revenue and metal for armaments.
But Gustavus Adolphus was much else besides a soldier. He was easily the most
creative administrator in Swedish history. Paunchy, jocose, explosive, this
roughhewn Nordic figure with big blue eyes and blond Vandyke beard obviously
bulged with manly energy, but he had deep reserves of religion and culture as
well. He recruited the Swedish nobility, led by the extremely able Chancellor
Axel Oxenstierna (1583-1654), into administrative service. He charmed the burghers
and peasants in the Riksdag. He bolstered his doughty Lutheran clergy,
and they in turn mixed patriotism with religion, performing such thankless
civil jobs as collecting the local taxes. Ashamed of Sweden’s backward school
system, the king founded many new schools and reorganized the faltering
University of Upsala.
Not being a magician, Gustavus Adolphus
failed to transform Sweden into a lasting great power. When he led his army
into Germany in 1630, to battle the Catholic Habsburgs, he committed his
country to aims beyond its resources. After Gustavus Adolphus was killed in
1632, the crown passed to his five-year-old daughter Christina (ruled
1632-1654). During her minority, Chancellor Oxenstierna doggedly kept Sweden in
the endless German war. Swedish armies won more often than they lost, and by
peace treaties in 1645, 1648, and 1658 the Swedes gained considerable Danish
and German territory. Internally, however, the country lost its cohesion. Queen
Christina was partly responsible, for she was a selfish lady who grew bored
with statecraft, abdicated her throne, and shocked her people by converting to
Catholicism. The late seventeenth century saw a swift eclipse of Sweden’s
great-power status. Between 1700 and 1809 it lost the whole of its Baltic empire
to Russia. Sweden’s age of greatness was thus short—but decisive. To see how
pivotal Gustavus Adolphus’ Lutheran crusade was in the 1630’s, let us return to
the Holy Roman Empire and the international power struggle which devastated
Germany.
THE THIRTY YEARS’ WAR, 1618-1648
Other wars have lasted as long, have
caused as much damage, and have settled as little. But the Thirty Years’ War,
which opened in Bohemia in 1618 and convulsed central Europe for a generation',
had one peculiar feature. The chief combatants (after the first few years)
were non-German, yet their combat took place almost entirely on German soil.
The most populous provinces of the Holy Roman Empire became a playground for
the invading armies of Spain, Denmark, Sweden, and France. How and why did the
German people suffer this indignity?
In 1618, the Habsburg heir apparent to the
imperial throne was Ferdinand of Styria (1578-1637), a cheerful, bustling
little man of forty. Ferdinand was a rabid Catholic, educated and counseled by
the Jesuits. He was frankly unwilling to tolerate Protestantism among his
subjects. Clearly, this man was going to make a more energetic Holy Roman
emperor than anyone since Charles V, but the Protestant imperial princes were
none too alarmed. Not even the great Charles V had been able to exercise much
power as emperor. Within the Austrian and Bohemian provinces held directly by
the Habsburgs, however, the situation was different. Here Ferdinand did have
real power. As soon as he was crowned king of Bohemia in 1617, he began to
rescind the religious toleration guaranteed to the Bohemian Protestants by his
cousin, Rudolf II, in 1609. The Bohemians were in much the same predicament as
the Netherlanders had been in the 1560’s—alienated from their autocratic Habsburg
prince by language, custom, and religion. As in the Netherlands, the nobility
engineered rebellion. On May 23, 1618, a hundred armed Bohemian noblemen
cornered Ferdinand’s two most hated Catholic advisers in the council room of
the Hradschin castle, in Prague, and tossed them out the window into the castle
ditch some fifty feet below. The victims survived the fall, perhaps (according
to the Catholic view) becausc they were rescued in mid-flight by guardian
angels, or perhaps (according to the Protestant view) because they landed on a
dung heap. At any rate this “defenestration of Prague” put the rebels in charge
of the Bohemian capital. Their announced aim was to preserve ancient Bohemian
privileges and to rescue King Ferdinand from the wicked Jesuits. But they were
really repudiating Habsburg rule.
The crisis quickly spread from Bohemia to
the entire empire. The aged emperor, Matthias, died in 1619, giving the German
Protestant princes a golden chance to join the rebellion against Habsburg rule.
Seven electors had the exclusive right to choose Matthias’ successor: the three
Catholic archbishops of Mainz, Trier, and Cologne; the three Protestant
princes of Saxony, Brandenburg, and the Palatinate; and the king of Bohemia.
If the Protestant electors denied Ferdinand’s right to vote as king of Bohemia,
they could block his election as Holy Roman emperor. But only Elector Frederick
V of the Palatinate (1596-1632) turned out to be willing to do this, and he
backed down. On August 28, 1619, at Frankfurt, the electors unanimously cast
their votes for Emperor Ferdinand II. A few hours after his election, Ferdinand
learned that the Bohemian rebels in Prague had deposed him as their king and
elected Frederick of the Palatinate in his place! Frederick accepted the Bohemian
crown. A general war was now inevitable. Emperor Ferdinand prepared to crush
his rebel subjects and lo punish the German prince who had dared to usurp his
hereditary 1 labsburn lands.
The Bohemian rebellion was poorly
conceived from the start. The rebels sorely missed a folk hero equivalent to
John Huss (c. 1369-1415) who had led the great Bohemian religious revolt two
centuries before. The members of the Bohemian nobility did not trust one
another. The Bohemian assembly hesitated to levy special taxes or build an
army. Having no native candidate to replace Ferdinand, the rebels had turned to
the German Calvinist Elector Palatine. But Frederick was a very poor choice. A
simple young fellow of twenty-three, he had no feeling for the Slavic evangelical
religion he was being asked to champion, nor could lie supply men and money
with which to fight the Habsburgs. The Bohemians counted on the other German
princes to support King Frederick’s cause, but very few did so. Frederick’s
foreign friends, such as his father-in-law, James I of England, also stayed
neutral.
The rebels’ best hope lay in the weakness
of Ferdinand II. The emperor had no army of his own and little means of raising
one; in the Austrian Habsburg lands, most of the nobility and the provincial
estates were in league with the rebel Bohemians. But Ferdinand was able to buy
the services of three allies. Maximilian (1573-1651), duke of Bavaria and the
most powerful German Catholic prince, sent an army into Bohemia on the promise
that the emperor would cede him Frederick’s electoral dignity and some of his
Palatine land. Philip III of Spain likewise sent his Habsburg cousin an army,
in return for the promised cession of the remaining Palatine land. More
surprising, the Lutheran elector of Saxony also helped reconquer Bohemia, his
reward being the Habsburg province of Lusatia. The result of these shabby
bargains was a quick military campaign (1620-1622) in which the rebels were
utterly defeated. The Bavarian army easily routed the Bohemians at the Battle
of White Mountain in 1620. From the Alps to the Oder, throughout the Habsburg
lands, the rebels capitulated and were left to Ferdinand’s tender mercies. The
Bavarian and the Spanish armies next conquered the Palatinate. Foolish
Frederick was dubbed the Winterkonig (“king of one winter”). By 1622, he
had lost not merely his Bohemian crown but all his German territories as well.
The war did not end in 1622, though the
original issues had now been resolved. One cause of continuing conflict was the
emergence of private armies led by soldiers of fortune. Ernst von Mansfeld
(1580-1626) was at first the most prominent of these mercenary captains. By
birth a Belgian Catholic, Mansfeld had fought for the Spanish before turning
Calvinist and selling his services to Frederick and the Bohemians. He
subsequently switched sides several times, always working for the highest
bidder. Since Mansfeld supported his army by looting the towns and villages
through which he passed, he preferred to keep moving into fresh territory.
After Frederick’s defeat in 1622, Mansfeld—a law unto himself, less bent on
fighting than on plundering—took his army into northwestern Germany. Maximilian
of Bavaria kept his army in the field against Mansfeld. His troops did not
subdue the captain, but they harried the German Protestant civilian population
of the area ruthlessly. Maximilian was doing well from the war: he had snatched
much of Frederick’s land, and his seat as an elector, and the emperor owed him
large sums of money; so Maximilian was none too anxious for peace. Foreign
Protestant princes, who had stayed neutral in 1618-1619, now started to
intervene in imperial affairs. In 1625, King Christian IV of Denmark (ruled
1588-1648), whose province of Holstein was within the Holy Roman Empire,
entered the war as protector of the Protestants in northern Germany. Christian
was anxious to prevent a total Catholic conquest of the empire, but he also
hoped to profit as Maximilian had done from the fluid situation. He was an
abler leader than Frederick and had a better army, but he could find no German
allies. The Protestant electors of Saxony and Brandenburg wanted the war to
end, and they declined to join the Protestant cause. In 1626 Maximilian’s
veterans crushed Christian at the Battle of Lutter and drove him back into
Denmark.
So far, Emperor Ferdinand II had gained
the most from the war. The capitulation of the Bohemian rebels gave him a free
hand to suppress Protestantism, redistribute land, and revamp the
administration of his dynastic Habsburg possessions. The expulsion of Frederick
permitted him to tinker with the imperial constitution: by shifting the
Palatine electoral vote to Bavaria, Ferdinand obtained an unbreakable Catholic,
pro-Habsburg majority. The spread of the war into northern Germany enabled him
to eject additional rebel Protestant princes and to parcel out their
territories among his family and friends. By 1626' Ferdinand envisioned what
had been inconceivable in 1618, the transformation of the Holy Roman Empire
into an absolute, sovereign, Catholic, Habsburg state.
Obviously, Ferdinand’s war aims were not
quite compatible with those of his ally Maximilian. The emperor needed a more
pliant instrument than the Bavarian army. Yet he was deeply in debt to
Maximilian and could not subsidize an army of his own. This situation explains
his curious partnership with Albrecht von Wallenstein (1583-1634), a soldier of
fortune par excellence. A Bohemian Protestant by birth, Wallenstein had sided
with the Habsburgs during the Bohemian revolt, and built a fabulous private
fortune in the process. Of all the leading participants in the Thirty Years’
War, Wallenstein was the most enigmatic. A tall, baleful figure, he exhibited
most of the unpleasant personality traits one expects in an impatient parvenu.
He was unscrupulous, greedy, reckless, cruel, quarrelsome, and superstitious. A
promoter on the grandest scale, Wallenstein evidently set no limits to his
ambitions. All of his contemporaries feared and distrusted the man; it is
impossible for a modern analyst to be sure just what he was up to. In 1625 he
contracted to field an imperial army at his own expense and was authorized by
Ferdinand to requisition food and shelter from the unfortunate districts he
occupied. Wallenstein once asserted that he could maintain an army of fifty
thousand more easily than an army of twenty thousand, because the larger force
could more thoroughly squeeze the land off which it was living. For a while
Wallenstein cooperated with the Bavarian general Tilly. But he preferred to
campaign independently. lie chased Mansfeld out of the empire, and occupied
much of Denmark and much of the German Baltic coast. By 1628, he commanded
125,000 men. The emperor made him duke of Mecklenburg, one of the newly
conquered Baltic provinces. Neutral princes, such as the elector of
Brandenburg, were powerless to stop Wallenstein from occupying their
territory. Even Maximilian, belatedly aware of the emperor’s new power, pleaded
with Ferdinand to dismiss his overmighty general.
By 1629, the emperor felt the time had
come to issue his Edict of Restitution, perhaps his fullest expression of
autocratic power. Ferdinand’s edict outlawed Calvinism within the Holy Roman
Empire, and required the Lutherans to disgorge all Church properties they had confiscated
since 1552. Sixteen bishoprics, twenty-eight cities and towns, and over one
hundred and fifty monasteries and convents scattered throughout northern and
central Germany were ordered restored to Rome. Ferdinand acted unilaterally,
without recourse to an imperial Diet. The Catholic princes felt almost as
menaced as the Protestant princes by the Edict of Restitution, for the emperor
was trampling their constitutional liberties and enhancing his centralized
authority. Wallenstein’s soldiers soon occupied the cities of Magdeburg,
Halberstadt, Bremen, and Augsburg, which had been predominantly Protestant for
many years, and forcibly converted them to Catholicism. There seemed to be no
reason why, with the help of Wallenstein’s army, Ferdinand could not soon
abrogate the whole Augsburg formula of 1555 and transform the empire into a
Catholic absolute monarchy.
It was at this crucial moment in 1630 that Gustavus Adolphus thrust
his Swedish army into Germany. He announced that he was coming to protect German
Protestantism and constitutional liberties from Ferdinand II’s attacks, but he
was also obviously looking for conquest and profit. The Swedish king suffered
from the same handicap as the previous would-be Protestant champion, King
Christian of Denmark: he was a foreigner without German allies. Luckily for
Gustavus Adolphus, Ferdinand II played into his hands. Feeling securely in
command of Germany, Ferdinand called upon the imperial Diet in 1630 to
recognize his son as heir to the imperial throne and to help the Spanish
Habsburgs against the Dutch and the French. The emperor’s plans were recklessly
ambitious, and he underestimated the German princes’ hostility toward him. The
princes refused both of his requests, even after he tried to placate them by
dismissing Wallenstein from command of the imperial army. All that Ferdinand
had accomplished was to remove his best general. Meanwhile, Gustavus Adolphus
had a second stroke of luck. The French government, headed by Cardinal
Richclicu, agreed to subsidize his invasion of Germany. Obviously, the French
cardinal had no interest in Gustavus Adolphus’ Protestant crusade. Nonetheless,
he agreed to pay the Swedes a million livres a year to maintain an army of thirty-six thousand in Germany, because he wanted to harass the
Habsburgs, paralyze the empire, and stake out French claims to Rhenish
territory. All that Gustavus Adolphus now needed was enough German support so
that he could play the role of avenging hero. It was no easy task, but he
finally badgered the electors of Brandenburg and Saxony into signing alliances
witli Sweden. Now he could take action.
In 1631 Gustavus Adolphus smashed the
imperial army at Breitenfeld; this was probably the most decisive battle of the
Thirty Years’ War, for it wiped out at a stroke most of the Catholic gains of
1618-1629. During the next year he systematically occupied the heretofore
unspoiled Catholic regions in central Germany. Bavaria was sacked with special
thoroughness. The Swedish king prepared to invade Habsburg Austria and acted
more and more as if he intended to usurp Ferdinand's place as Holy Roman
emperor.
Gustavus Adolphus’ intervention was
pivotal because he saved German Protestantism and defeated Habsburg imperial
centralization, but his personal triumph was very brief. In 1632 Wallenstein
came out of retirement to fight him. Emperor Ferdinand had already begged his
general to resume command of the imperial forces, and when Wallenstein finally
took the field, his army was more than ever a personal instrument. On a dark,
foggy November day in 1632 the two great commanders met at Liitzen, in Saxony.
Their armies locked savagely, blindly. Gustavus Adolphus galloped into the fog
on a cavalry charge, and shortly his horse careered back, wounded and
riderless. The Swedish troops, maddened at the loss of their king, drove
Wallenstein’s army from the battlefield. In the darkness and the mud they
finally found Gustavus Adolphus’ bullet-riddled corpse, stripped to the shirt
by scavengers. “O,” cried one of his grieving soldiers, “would to God I had
such a leader again to fight such another day; in this old quarrel!”2
Old quarrel indeed, by 1632—and after
Liitzen a hopeless deadlock. None of the combatants was strong enough to win,
or weak enough to surrender. Wallenstein, once again the most feared soldier in
Germany, had a brief chance to engineer a compromise peace settlement.
Unencumbered by religious passion or by loyalty to the house of Habsburg, he
was ready to deal with anyone who would pay handsomely for his services. In
1633 he campaigned as little as possible for the emperor, while dickering
simultaneously with all of Ferdinand’s enemies: the German Protestants, the
Bohemian rebels, the Swedes, and the French. But Wallenstein was by now too
sickly and irresolute to play this dangerous game. In February, 1634, Ferdinand
II dismissed him from command, and instructed his new general to capture
Wallenstein dead or alive. Wallenstein was in winter quarters at Pilsen, in
Bohemia. He appealed to his officers to fight for him rather than for the
emperor, but they mutinied against him. With a few companions, he fled from
Pilsen, but they were quickly cornered. The final scene was sordid enough: an
Irish mercenary captain kicked open Wallenstein’s bedchamber door, speared his
unarmed chieftain, rolled the bloody body in a carpet, and dragged it
unceremoniously down the stairs.
For the moment, Ferdinand II scarcely
missed Wallenstein’s military talents. In 1634 imperial forces decimated the
Swedes at Nordlingen, and the following year the emperor made peace with
Sweden’s German allies, Saxony and Brandenburg. Yet the war was far from over.
In 1635 France under Richelieu poured fresh men and money into Germany to
compensate for Swedish reverses. The combatants were now France and Sweden
versus Spain and the emperor. The war had become a Habsburg-Bourbon dynastic
struggle, with the original religious, ethnic, and constitutional issues laid
aside. Very few Germans wanted to continue fighting after 1635; most of them
tried to stay neutral. Their lands, however, continued to be the battlefields,
and their property continued to be pillaged.
The final thirteen years of the war, from
1635 to 1648, were the most destructive. The Franco-Swedish armies generally
maintained the upper hand, but their objective was to keep the war going rather
than to strike a knockout blow against their Habsburg opponents. It is
noticeable that the French and the Swedes rarely invaded Habsburg Austria and
never sacked the emperor’s personal lands the way they sacked central Germany
and Bavaria. Troops on both sides expended far more energy in looting than in
fighting. One eyewitness, Hans Jacob Christoffel von Grimmelshausen
(1625-1676), drew on his own experience to write a graphic account of the
closing years of combat. In The Adventures of a Simpleton, Grimmelshausen
follows a naive peasant boy through one disaster after another; soldiers and
civilians routinely torture and kill one another, with the civilians always
getting the worst of it. In this style of warfare, every army had its train of
camp followers—women and children—who kept the troops comfortable enough so
that they were willing to campaign indefinitely. Except for the plague
epidemics at many campsites, military life in mid-seventeenth-century Germany
was definitely more safe and pleasant than civilian life. The numerous German
towns were prime targets: Marburg was occupied eleven times; Magdeburg was
besieged ten times. But at least town dwellers could sometimes withstand sieges
behind their walls or buy off a conquering army. The exposed peasantry, on the
other hand, had no defense except to run away. Agricultural collapse triggered
famine. The total population loss was staggering, even when one discounts the
estimates of contemporaries who exaggerated their figures wildly in order to
claim damages or plead tax exemption. The German cities lost one third of their
population, and the rural areas two fifths of their population, during the
course of the war. The empire had seven or eight million fewer inhabitants in
1648 than in 1618. Not until the twentieth century could any other European
conflict boast such human butchery.
Peace negotiations opened in 1644, but
four years passed before the multitude of diplomats congregated in Westphalia
finally settled on terms and ended the war. After all this haggling, the Peace
of Westphalia (1648) turned out to be essentially a confirmation of the
long-scorned Peace of Augsburg. The Holy Roman Empire remained politically
fragmented, divided into three hundred autonomous, sovereign princely states,
most of them very small and weak. The emperor, now Ferdinand II’s son,
Ferdinand III (ruled 1637—1657), had meager executive authority beyond his own
family lands. The imperial Diet, in which all the sovereign princes were
represented, continued to be moribund. Thus the Habsburg hope of welding the
empire into a single, absolute state was dashed once again, this time
permanently. The Peace of Westphalia also reaffirmed the Augsburg formula of
territorial churches. Each prince kept the right to establish Catholicism,
Lutheranism, or Calvinism (prohibited in 1555) within his state. A greater
effort was made now than in 1555 to guarantee private liberty of conscience to
Catholics living in Protestant states and vice versa, but in fact most Germans
docilely accepted the creed of their ruler. Anabaptists and members of other
sects excluded from the Westphalia formula continued to suffer persecution.
Thousands of them emigrated to America, especially to Pennsylvania, in the
eighteenth century. After 1648 the northern half of the empire was pretty
solidly Lutheran, and the southern half pretty solidly Catholic, with important
pockets of Calvinism along the Rhine. In no other part of Europe did
Protestants and Catholics achieve such a state of balanced deadlock.
Almost all of the major combatants in the
Thirty Years’ War gained some territory at the Peace of Westphalia. France
annexed parts of Alsace and Lorraine. Sweden annexed
western Pomerania, on the Baltic coast. Bavaria kept part of the Palatine
territory and the electoral scat it had grabbed at the beginning of the war.
Saxony kept Lusatia. Brandenburg, considering its passive role in the war, did
exceptionally well in annexing eastern Pomerania and Magdeburg. Even the son of
Frederick V, the would-be king of Bohemia, was taken care of: he was restored
to his father’s Palatinate (considerably reduced in size) and given a new
eighth seat in the electoral college. The Swiss Confederation and the Dutch
republic were recognized as independent of the Holy Roman Empire. Neither the
Spanish nor the Austrian Habsburgs gained any territory in 1648, but the
Austrian Habsburgs still had much the largest bloc of imperial land, and
Ferdinand III exercised far firmer political and religious control over Austria
and Bohemia than had his father before the Bohemian rebellion. It is hard to
argue that anyone gained enough at the Peace of Westphalia to justify thirty
years of fighting. But the settlement of 1648 did prove to be unusually stable.
Except for some details, the intricate German political boundaries were not
redrawn thereafter until the time of Napoleon. The religious boundaries lasted
into the twentieth century.
The Peace of Westphalia ended the wars of
religion in central Europe and left Germany a mere geographical expression.
Ever since 1648, the Thirty Years’ War has had a continuously bad reputation.
Statesmen of the late seventeenth and eighteenth centuries looked back on it as
a model of how not to conduct warfare. In their view, the Thirty Years’
War demonstrated the dangers of religious passion, and of amateur armies led by
soldiers of fortune. The philosophers and kings of the age of reason, having
discovered a controlled style of warfare with armies professional enough to
reduce brigandage and defection, and objectives limited enough to negotiate
with minimum bloodshed, scorned the uncivilized, inefficient seventeenth-cen-
tury wars of religion. To observers in the nineteenth century, the Thirty
Years’ War seemed calamitous for a different reason: because it blocked for so
long the national unification of Germany. Twentieth-century observers may no
longer feel so certain of the virtues of national unification, but they still
criticize the Thirty Years’ War for its ideological posturing and civilian
atrocities. One historian has summed up her feelings about this conflict as
follows: “Morally subversive, economically destructive, socially degrading,
confused in its causes, devious in its course, futile in its result, it is the
outstanding example in European history of meaningless conflict.”3
This judgment may be unduly harsh. But for most Germans the war must indeed
have been a miserable, profitless experience.
THE RISE OF AUSTRIA AND BRANDENBURG-PRUSSIA
During the second half of the seventeenth
century, the Holy Roman Empire was a phantom state, a much revered and very
elaborate constitutional mechanism which no longer worked. The princes’ final
victory over the emperor at Westphalia confirmed the imperial government’s inability
to enforce orders, pass laws, raise taxes, mount armies, or conduct foreign
policy. Sovereignty could be found only at the local level, in the three
hundred princely states and imperial cities. In these petty states (the average
population was only forty thousand), there was a prevailing late
seven-teenth-century tendency toward political absolutism. Each prince wanted
to have his own small standing army, in case another general war should break
out. Many princes suppressed or restricted their representative assemblies.
Many built expensive Baroque palaces, gaudy symbols of power, and surrounded
themselves with courtiers and ceremonial functionaries in conscious imitation
of Louis XIV at Versailles. Armies and courts cost money, which the imperial princes
collected through a variety of crude taxes—excises, tariffs, and river tolls.
These taxes impaired commerce. A cargo shipped four hundred miles down the
Rhine from Basel to Cologne had to pass through thirty political jurisdictions
and was subject to so many tariffs and tolls that the shipment
was impractical. Because of the handicaps imposed upon business, German towns
suffered continuing losses in population, wealth, and importance. Just as the
princes exercised sovereign power in regulating (or overregulating) domestic
commerce, so they exercised sovereign power in conducting international
relations. The treaty of 1648 recognized their right to make alliances with
foreign states. In the latter half of the seventeenth century, France was
always able to buy allies among the imperial princes while she was attacking
imperial territory. Thus in the 1670’s, when Louis XIV invaded the Rhineland,
twenty thousand Germans served in his army. Though the emperor induced the
imperial Diet to declare war against France, many west German states refused to
contribute to the imperial war effort, and six of the eight electors remained
clients of Louis XIV.
With the empire a hollow facade, interest
focuses on the several German states which were large enough after 1648 to
function in the international power structure. Two German states, Austria and
Brandenburg, developed vigorously during the second half of the century. The
Habsburgs transformed their dynastic Austrian possessions into a great new
Danubian monarchy, while in northern Germany the Hohenzollerns of Brandenburg
laid the foundations for another great new state, the eighteenth-century
kingdom of Prussia. Three other German states, Bavaria, Saxony, and the
Palatinate, seemingly had as much chance as Brandenburg to build their strength
during the late seventeenth century, but all three failed to do so. The Elector
Palatine was peculiarly unlucky, for no sooner did his people begin to recover
from the Thirty Years’ War than the Palatinate was twice overrun and devastated
by Louis XIV. The elector of Saxony dissipated his energy and his country’s
wealth in trying to secure election as king of Poland. The elector of Bavaria,
who had earlier played a key role in the Catholic reformation and in the Thirty
Years’ War, now poured all his resources into his Munich court; in
international affairs, Bavaria became a French satellite. The relative failure
of these western and central German states, and the success of Austria and
Brandenburg, meant among other things that German and imperial leadership would
henceforth come from east of the Elbe. Both the Habsburgs and the Hohenzollerns
ruled over territories situated on the eastern border of the empire; both faced
east during the late seventeenth century and built their new states at the
expense of the Ottoman Turks, Poland, and Sweden.
Austria
The rise of Austria was the most striking
phenomenon in eastern Europe during the late seventeenth century. It was a
story of luck as much as skill. The Habsburg dynasty which built the new
Danubian monarchy—Ferdinand II (ruled 1619-1637), Ferdinand III (ruled
1637-1657), and Leopold I (ruled 1658-1705)—was not remarkable for talent.
Habsburg Austria was a unique creation, a crossbreed between a centralized
western nation state like France and an old-style dynastic empire like Charles
V’s miscellaneous collection of territories. The reigning Habsburg prince,
besides being Holy Roman emperor, was simultaneously archduke of Upper and
Lower Austria, margrave of Styria, duke of Carinthia and Carniola, count of
Tyrol, king of Bohemia, margrave of Moravia, duke of Upper and Lower Silesia,
king of Hungary, Croatia, Slavonia, and Dalmatia, and prince of Transylvania—
though in fact the last five of these territories were mainly possessed by the
Turks until the end of the century. The Habsburgs managed each of these
provinces separately. Every province had its individual native customs and
institutional patterns. Several, notably Bohemia and Hungary, boasted long,
proud histories of resistance to foreign rule. The Habsburgs’ subjects spoke
some ten languages and practiced at least eight religious creeds. No part of
Europe was more heterogeneous ethnically and culturally. Though the Habsburg
lands were physically contiguous, their peoples shared little except the
accident of common allegiance to one ruling dynasty. It was the Habsburg
ambition to secure absolute control over each and every province, to chase the
Turks out of Hungary and adjoining areas, and to cultivate certain cultural and
social uniformities which would make their subjects easier to handle. But the
Habsburgs did not want to weld these diverse peoples into a single
political unit equivalent to France or England. On the contrary, they preferred
to play one.province against another. The Danubian monarchy was an atomistic
congeries, each province separate from its neighbors, each province bound as
tightly as possible to the Habsburg crown.
This new Danubian monarchy began to take
shape as early as the 1620’s, when Ferdinand II reorganized Bohemia, Moravia,
and Austria in the wake of the abortive Bohemian rebellion. Since the rebellion
had been initiated by the nobility in these provinces, Ferdinand confiscated
the huge estates of the rebel nobles and redistributed the forfeited lands
among loyal Habsburg supporters. Many mercenary captains of the Thirty Years’
War (Wallenstein was among them) became members of an acquisitive new landlord
class in Bohemia and Moravia. Ferdinand also expelled all Protestant clergymen
and school teachers, replacing them as far as possible with Jesuit
missionaries. He had remarkable success in making almost all the Bohemian
people rejoin the Catholic Church. Bohemia, bastion of the Hussite movement
for more than two centuries, was the only thoroughly Protestantized community
to be reconverted to Rome during the wars of religion.
The Austrian Habsburgs held rather fixed
ideas about the good society. Devotion to the dynasty and to the Virgin Mary
was supposed to give their subjects spiritual and moral strength. A big
standing army provided the muscle. A small educated class provided the priests
and civil servants. The German language was considered superior to the Slavic
languages; hence German culture was mandatory for the ruling elite. Yet the
Habsburgs were cosmopolitan enough to attract men of every European nationality
into their employ. Agricultural landlords were encouraged to exploit the
peasantry but were discouraged from taking active part in governmental
administration or legislation. Thus in Bohemia and Moravia the once-powerful
estates met seldom in the middle and late seventeenth century, and did little
except to legislate the imposition of serfdom on the peasant population. The
new landlords, perhaps more businesslike than their rebel predecessors, saw
that they could farm very profitably if they could get free agricultural labor.
Despite peasant revolts, the Habsburg government required of each Bohemian
peasant three days of unpaid compulsory service (robota) for his lord
every week. Like the Polish landlords, the Bohemian and Austrian agricultural
magnates produced for export. They raised grain and timber for the western
European market, and meat, grain, and fish (bred in elaborate fishponds) for
the Habsburg army. In this overwhelmingly rural, stratified society the Czech
and Austrian towns served few functions, and during the seventeenth century
they decayed even more completely than the towns of western Germany.
The Habsburgs needed outside help in order
to reconquer Bohemia in the 1620’s, and again to regain control of Hungary in
the 1680’s and 1690’s. The Habsburg-Turkish demarcation line in Hungary had
been fairly stable since the mid-sixteenth century. The Turkish frontier
garrisons were only eighty miles east of Vienna, the Habsburg capital. In the
1660’s, the Turks renewed their efforts to conquer Austria. Though the
Habsburgs beat back an invading Ottoman army in 1664, Leopold I was so alarmed
at the Turks’ military strength that he paid the sultan a tribute of 200,000
florins in order to secure a truce. As soon as the truce expired in 1683,
another huge Turkish army advanced through Hungary, crossed the Austrian
border, and laid siege to Vienna. Leopold fled his capital. For two months the
Viennese hung on desperately. In the nick of time a relief army of Austrians,
Germans, and Poles commanded by King John Sobieski of Poland (ruled 1674— 1696)
routed the Ottomans, and sent the dreaded janissaries reeling back down the
Danube. This great victory opened Hungary to reconquest. In sixteen years of
hard fighting, the forces of the Austrian Habsburgs, the papacy, Poland, and
Venice, in a coalition known as the Holy League, drove the Turks south of the
Danube and east of the Carpathians. The League armies were led at various times
by Polish, Italian, Rhenish, Bavarian, and Saxon commanders. At the Peace of
Karlowitz in 1699, the Turks surrendered a huge belt of territory to the
Habsburgs: Hungary, Transylvania, Slavonia, and Croatia. The Danubian monarchy
had doubled in size since 1648.
The Habsburgs’ efforts at reorganization
were not quite so successful in Hungary as they had been in Bohemia. The
Hungarians, or Magyars, had long resented Habsburg overlordship, partly because
the dynasty was foreign, partly because the Habsburgs had done little to rescue
Hungary from the Turks, and partly because the Habsburgs’ absolutist, Catholic
program encroached upon Hungarian “liberties.” These liberties were strictly
confined to the nobility. Like their counterparts everywhere in eastern Europe,
the Magyar landlords kept their serfs in thralldom while demanding total
freedom for themselves. In Royal Hungary, the western strip which the Turks had
never conquered, the nobility counted among their liberties the right to elect
their king (as in Poland) and to govern themselves through their estates. In
Transylvania, the eastern province which the Turks had only nominally
conquered, the nobility operated an independent republic, which was staunchly
Calvinist to boot. The Habsburgs had their best chance to reshape the society
in central and southern Hungary, the area which had been directly under Turkish
rule for 150 years. When they expelled the Turks in the 1680’s and 1690’s, the
Habsburgs sold or gave as much as possible of the newly acquired land to their
army officers and to others presumably dependent on the crown. But these new
landlords quickly melted into the Magyar nobility. It was quite impossible for
the Habsburgs to govern this frontier country without the cooperation of the
local magnates. Because they had to convince the Magyar nobility that Austrian
rule was at the very least preferable to Turkish, they dared not impose
absolutism or Catholicism too nakedly. In 1687 Leopold did get the Magyars to
surrender their elective monarchy; thereafter, the Hungarian crown was a
hereditary Habsburg possession. But the Hungarian estates retained real power,
and the Protestant nobility kept their religion. As commercial farming developed
in Hungary, the peasants (many of whom were Slovaks and Croats) sank deeper
into serfdom. They had to fulfill heavy obligations to their Magyar masters and
pay heavy taxes to the Austrian government as well—taxes from which the
landlord class was exempt. Habsburg Hungary, with its autocratic Austrian
ruler, its selfish Magyar aristocracy, its downtrodden Slavic peasantry, its
few small towns inhabited by Germans and Jews, was a melting pot in which
nothing melted.
Brandenburg-Prussia
Compared with the growth of Habsburg
Austria, the development of Hohenzollern Brandenburg during the late
seventeenth century was modest. The key figure here was Frederick William,
elector of Brandenburg from 1640 to 1688, who is known as the Great Elector.
Frederick William was the shrewdest ruler of his day in eastern Europe, but his
contemporaries may be pardoned for failing to notice his ability, since he
governed a small state and did nothing spectacular during his reign. The Great
Elector was an institutional innovator whose policies bore fruit long after his
death. Because the later Hohenzollern princes followed his recipe in building
the eighteenth-century kingdom of Prussia and the nineteenth-century German empire,
the Great Elector’s reign is of special historical interest.
In 1640 Frederick William inherited the
Hohenzollern family’s scattered collection of underdeveloped north German
territories, devastated by the Thirty Years’ War. He was a Calvinist; his
subjects were mainly Lutherans. Brandenburg was his chief possession, a flat
country with unproductive sandy soil, cut off from the Baltic coast, whose
several hundred thousand inhabitants raised grain and brewed beer. Berlin, the
chief town in Brandenburg, was a small place. More than a hundred miles east
of Brandenburg, beyond the imperial border and enveloped by Poland, lay
Prussia, the Elector’s second most important province. Here was a region of
forests and lakes, its chief center the commercial town of KSnigsberg. More
than a hundred miles west of Brandenburg, near the Dutch frontier, lay the
Elector’s remaining small outposts, Cleve, Mark, and Ravensburg. These
provinces all had their own autonomous estates, and being widely separated
from each other and only recently joined under the Hohenzollern dynasty, they
shared no common interests. Brandenburg and Prussia were both completely
dominated by the Junkers, the noble landlords. Like the landed gentry in
England and the szlachta in Poland, the Junkers had climbed to
power and prosperity by extracting concessions from the ruler above them while
squeezing the peasantry below. The Junkers had a reputation for being
shrewd, tough, and boorish. During the period of rapid inflation in the late
sixteenth century, they had pushed the sale price of their rye up 247 per cent
while paying their laborers wages which
had risen only 86 per cent. But by 1640
even the Junkers were in poor shape, for their Baltic grain trade was
disrupted by the Thirty Years’ War.
Frederick William set out to build an
effective state with these unpromising materials. His basic decision was to
create a permanent standing army. All his other political, social, and
economic innovations stemmed from the army’s role in centralizing the
Hohenzollern state. During the closing stage of the Thirty Years’ War,
Frederick William fielded eight thousand efficient troops, a lilliputian
display by great-power standards, but enough to clear the foreign soldiers
from his land and to give him a voice at the peace conference at Westphalia. In
1648 the Great Elector rather surprisingly gained more territory than any other
German prince: eastern Pomerania and several secularized bishoprics, including
Magdeburg. So far so good. Naturally, the several estates of Brandenburg,
Prussia, and Cleve-Mark wanted the army disbanded once the war was over, but
instead Frederick William kept on fighting. In the 1650’s he first joined
Sweden against Poland and then joined Poland against Sweden. He fought for
purely opportunistic reasons and changed sides whenever he seemed likely to
benefit as a result. In the 1670’s and 1680’s he outdid himself by switching
between the Dutch and the French three times. Frederick William was at war
about half the time during his long reign. By 1688 he had thirty thousand
professional troops.
Who was going to pay for this army? The
Elector knew that he could not let his soldiers live off the land in the manner
of Wallenstein’s mercenaries. Nor could he pay for them himself, though his
large private landholdings produced enough income to cover the ordinary
expenses of civil government. Foreign subsidies would help, but the cost would
have to be met chiefly through taxes, which the several estates adamantly
refused to approve. In 1653 the Elector worked out a compromise with the Brandenburg
estates whereby he recognized the special economic and social privileges of the
Junker landlords in return for what turned out to be a permanent tax to
maintain his army. The Elector acknowledged that only Junkers could own
land, that Junkers could freely evict peasants (who were all assumed to
be serfs) from lands they occupied, and that Junkers were immune from
taxation. On the other hand, he severely curtailed the political privileges of
the Brandenburg Junkers. After the army tax expired, he kept right on
collecting it and soon imposed an additional excise tax on the towns, without
the consent of the estates. In his Rhineland territories, the Elector bullied
the estates into levying army taxes by threatening to send his soldiers to
collect the money by force. In Prussia, resistance was stouter. To force the
estates to levy his taxes, Frederick William imprisoned the two chief leaders
of the opposition and executed one of them; he billeted his troops in
Konigsberg until the taxes were collected.
Frederick William’s subjects paid twice as
much per capita in taxes as Louis XIV’s much richer subjects; in a state with
little surplus wealth, and with the only affluent class—the Junkers—exempted
from taxation, the burden of supporting the army was truly crushing. However,
the Elector’s military exactions did produce some side benefits. To collect his
army taxes, Frederick William created a new bureaucratic institution, the Generalkriegs-
kommissariat, or military commissariat, which also disbursed army pay and
equipment, and soon supervised all phases of the state economy. The
commissariat officials, zealous servants of the Elector, worked hard to promote
new state-supported industry, especially the manufacture of military supplies.
Some twenty thousand persecuted Calvinist textile workers from France and the
Palatinate emigrated to Brandenburg, to the great benefit of the Elector’s
uniform-manufacturing industry. By the close of the century, the Hohenzollern
lands had recovered economically from the terrible damage of the Thirty Years’
War, and the population had climbed back to its early seventeenth-century level
of about 1.5 million persons.
The Great Elector’s standing army could
not make Brandenburg-Prussia into a great power overnight. His wars brought him
one paltry acquisition after 1648, a thirty-mile sliver of Pomeranian
territory. But Frederick William built enduring strength into his north German
society. The Elector’s army gave him and his heirs absolute political control.
It encouraged the people in habits of discipline and obedience. It contributed
to the unity of the state, for peasants from all the Hohenzollern provinces
were recruited into the rank and file, while Junkers from Brandenburg
and Prussia staffed the officer corps. It facilitated the growth of an
efficient bureaucracy. And it enabled Frederick William to capitalize upon the
existing rigid social stratification, the separation between privileged Junkers
and unprivileged serfs. To the aspiring Junker squire, an officer’s
commission became the proudest badge of his membership in the master class. The
Elector’s whole policy rested on partnership with the landlords. As for the
serfs, a clergyman observed in 1684, “the peasants are indeed human beings,”
but he went on to advise that they be treated like the stockfish, which is
“best when beaten well and soft.”4
The Great Elector’s son, Frederick III
(ruled 1688-1713), was a much less effective ruler. He acquired the royal title
of King in Prussia (considered less honorific than King of Prussia) in
1701, but played a secondary role in the great wars that filled his reign. The
first Hohenzollern ruler to take center stage in European affairs was Frederick
the Great, in the mid-eighteenth century. Eventually, under Bismarck’s
guidance, the Hohenzollerns would annex all the territory between Cologne and
Konigs- berg, and they would rule after 1871 as emperors of Germany. Compared
with Frederick the Great or Bismarck, the Great Elector is a small-scale
figure. But he started the fateful process by which Germany became politically
united.
At the close of the seventeenth century,
Brandenburg-Prussia and Austria were obviously organized along somewhat
differing lines. The Great Elector had worked to make his state homogeneous;
the Habsburgs cultivated heterogeneity. Brandenburg-Prussia was the more
militaristic and bureaucratic. Austria could not, or did not, extract from its
subjects as much money and service per capita as did Brandenburg-Prussia, but
since the Austrian population was much larger, Austria was nevertheless a far
greater power. Brandenburg-Prussia was Protestant, Austria was Catholic— but
this difference was decidedly less significant than it once would have been.
The two states gradually turned into strategic rivals, because both were headed
by German dynasties hoping to expand eastward. But this Austro-Prussian rivalry
should not obscure the fact that the two societies exhibited some striking
similarities in their parallel climbs to power in the seventeenth century.
For one thing, both Austria and Prussia
(as Brandenburg-Prussia came to be called) divorced sovereignty from
nationality, unlike contemporaneous western states. To be sure, Prussia was
not multinational, as Austria was. But in the eighteenth century Prussia
annexed more Polish territory than German, and before the French Revolution
demonstrated no Pan-German desire to embrace the whole German-speaking
population. Prussia and Austria were dynastic states, congeries of territories
their rulers happened to have inherited or conquered. Both the Hohenzollerns
and the Habsburgs achieved absolute, centralized political power by 1700. Both
managed to break the power of the representative estates, or diets. This
absolutism, however, could only be maintained at the cost of tacit partnership
with the landed magnates. The serf-owning lords everywhere east of the Elbe, in
Poland and Russia as in Austria and Prussia, consolidated their immense social
and economic privileges during the seventeenth century. The whole of eastern
Europe was profoundly agrarian. The town- dwelling merchants and lawyers, who
had often turned Calvinist in the sixteenth-century west and fought their kings
in the seventeenth-century west, had always been comparatively weak in Austria
and Prussia and lost strength steadily throughout the century. Thus by the
close of the century, though political disintegration had at last been
arrested, the social and economic disparity between east and west had by no
means been eliminated.
Chapter 3
The Psychology of Limited Wealth
A plague hospital in Vienna. The
civic authorities tried unsuccessfully to contain plague epidemics by
congregating the sick and burying the dead in pest- houses such as this.
Coinmaking. This sixteenth-century print shows the
primitive character of early modern industrialism. Workers equipped with
rudimentary tools pound metal into thin sheets, cut the sheets into coins, and
stamp and mill the coins—all by hand. Metropolitan Museum of Art.
The Harvesters. Painting by
Pieter Brueghel (the Elder). Note the total reliance on hand labor, the employment of women and children, and
the noontime picnic to speed the field work. The harvesters are cutting and
stacking the ripe grain as fast as they can, to prevent spoilage by rain. Metropolitan Museum of Art.
The Dutch
East India Company warehouse and timber wharf in Amsterdam. 7 his engraving by Muider shows a company ship
under construction, and lumber stockpiled for future shipbuilding.
Amsterdam harbor in 1663. Engraving by
Dapper, showing dozens of merchant ships moored outside the city because the
interior docks are jammed to capacity. Note the church steeples and windmills
silhouetted against the flat Holland countryside. Scheepvart Museum, Amsterdam.
European businessmen in the years between
1559 and 1715 faced problems and developed policies characteristic of a society
quite well off but very far from affluent. No longer did everyone have to
concentrate on the struggle for bare survival, as in the agrarian subsistence
economy of the early Middle Ages. The so-called ^commercial revolution was in
full swing, with the merchant the key figure, distributing more goods than ever
before to a 1 Worldwide market. The putting-out system of domestic
manufacturing was producing a rising volume and variety of consumer
commodities, especially textiles. A dramatic sixteenth-century increase in the
circulation of bullion spurred purchasing power. Refinements in credit
facilitated international commerce. Innovations in banking encouraged private
investment and public loans. The development of specialized commercial
agriculture, combined with improvements in the long-distance shipment of bulk
cargo, made it possible for big cities and densely populated regions to be fed from
distant farmlands. On the other hand, Europe did not yet have the economic
techniques to produce as much as its people needed for comfort, to say nothing
of abundance. Agriculture was still by far the largest occupation, and farming
methods were crude; the agrarian populace still had to expend most of its
energy in meeting its own needs rather than producing for the market.
Manufacturing was still done by hand rather than by machine. Transportation
remained slow and difficult. Commerce was extremely risky. Business enterprises
were typically small-scale. After about 1590, the population stopped growing.
Small wonder that in this era of rising yet limited wealth many Europeans clung
to the attitudes appropriate in a subsistence economy.
Europe’s.wealth, such as it was, was
unevenly distributed geographically. The commercial west held a vastly larger
share than the agrarian east. Within western Europe, the Atlantic ports were
the chief capitalist centers, Wealth was also very unevenly distributed among the
various social classes; indeed it was scarcely distributed at all. Everywhere
in Europe the distance between the propertied and the propertyless was
widening. Great property holders such as kings and landed magnates luxuriated
in unprecedented conspicuous consumption. Small and middling property holders,
independent farmers, artisans, shopkeepers, members of the learned professions,
and the like, typically got only a taste of wealth but hoped to acquire more by
copying the habits of the beaver and the squirrel. The propertyless bottom half
(or more) of society, the wage laborers, serfs, unemployed, and unemployables,
got nothing—and were told to expect nothing—beyond bare survival. In most of
Europe the laboring classes had somewhat harder working conditions and lower
living standards in 1715 than in 1559.
Also noteworthy is the fact that in this
period the politically consolidated national state clearly replaced the
city-state as the most effective business unit. The mercantilist policies of
Spain, France, and England—politically belligerent, but economically
conservative and protectionist—most fully express the sixteenth- and
seventeenth-century European psychology of limited wealth.
POPULATION
Our understanding of the most fundamental
aspect of life in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries—the population
pattern—is sadly deficient and likely to remain so. No government in this era
took a comprehensive census of its inhabitants. In some western states the
local clergy kept parish registers of baptisms, marriages, and deaths. Tax
collectors occasionally enumerated households. But statistical data of this
sort is spotty, inexact, and difficult to interpret, and for much of Europe—the
eastern regions in particular—there is really no quantifiable information at
all. Such fragmentary evidence as we do have indicates that Europe's
population, which had been severely depressed for a century after the Black
Death, began to grow in the mid-fifteenth century and continued on a strong
upward curve for more than a hundred years. By the late Sixteenth century the
total count was probably somewhat over a hundred million—or about a sixth of
the present figure. Around 1590 the population seems to have stopped growing
in most parts of Europe. Throughout the seventeenth century the overall picture
is one of demographic oscillation. Most states experienced sudden, sharp
population losses, followed (though not always) by gradual recovery. The
pattern varied significantly from place to place. Germany, as we have seen, lost
close to 40 per cent of its population during the Thirty Years’ War, but
recovered rapidly in the late seventeenth century. The Spanish population
dropped about 25 per cent between 1590 and 1665, and then leveled off. The
French population fell and rose irregularly without much net loss or gain
between 1590 and 1715. In England, the population grew some 30 per cent during
this time. But overall, as far as we can tell, Europe’s population in 1715 was
no larger, and probably somewhat smaller, than it had been in 1590.
Why did the population grow in the
sixteenth century? Why did it stop growing around 1590? Why did it fluctuate
during the seventeenth century? Demographers have no agreed-upon answers to
these questions, but the key variable they point to is the death rate, which
rose and fell wildly during our period. The birthrate was much more regular.
Wherever it has been measured in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, the
rate of births was high: 35 to 40 per thousand, far above the modern western rate.
In “good” times, without demographic crisis, the birthrate in early modern
Europe was sufficiently higher than the death rate to double the population
every century. Through the 1580’s, though growth was frequently checked by
war, pestilence, and famine, it was not stopped. Thereafter, demographic
catastrophe struck frequently and massively.
The 1590’s mark a watershed. From
Scandinavia to Spain, and from Hungary to Ireland, harvests were poor all
through this decade. We can pinpoint weather conditions with surprising
precision. In the Alpine valleys the glaciers advanced rapidly in the 1590’s,
a sign of very cold winters. During the years 1591-1597, French winegrowers
harvested their grapes very late, a sign of wet, cold summers.1 In
western Europe, wartime conditions intensified the famine by blocking
emergency food distribution. The Dutch and English fleets stopped grain
shipments to the Spanish Netherlands. Henry IV’s army stopped grain shipments
to Paris. The price of wheat rose fivefold in France between 1590 and 1593. It
is estimated that the French population suddenly dropped by three million—a
15-per-cent loss.
Comparable demographic crises occurred in
the 1620’s, the 1640’s, the 1690’s, and the 1710’s. We know the most about the
French harvest failure and famine of 1693-1694. Parish registers for this time
are much fuller than those for the earlier years, so it is possible to measure
the impact of the famine in striking detail. For example, the parish registers
for villages in the region of Beauvais, in northwestern France, show two to
four times the usual number of deaths in the twelve months following this
harvest failure. Furthermore, whereas in a normal year two thirds of those
dying were young children or old people, the registers show that in 1693-1694
over half were adults of prime working age. In other words, the subsistence
crisis crippled the labor force, maimed family structure, and impeded
procreation. If we check the registers for babies conceived during the famine
year, we find less than half the usual number.2 There are several
reasons for this sudden drop in fertility. Some sex partners died, some were
too weak to procreate, and some may have aborted their children in despair. It
is also probable that the semistarved women who survived the famine experienced
such extreme nutritional losses that they were temporarily unable to menstruate
or ovulate. This sort of famine- induced infecundity has been observed among
slave women on West Indian plantations in the eighteenth century, and among
both civilians and concentration-camp inmates during the Second World War. In
the case of the seventeenth-century French peasant women, recovery of fertility
was rapid. The registers show that in 1695-1696 they bore more children than in
a normal year. Yet the demographic impact of this famine obviously lingered for
years.
Even in times of desperate hunger people
seldom literally starve to death. More generally they become too weak to resist
common diseases such as influenza or dysentery. In the sixteenth and
seventeenth centuries, there were the added perils of typhus and the bubonic
plague— diseases that killed the strong as well as the weak and struck the
crowded, unsanitary cities with special frequency and force. Every European
city was repeatedly thinned by the plague. To cite a few extreme examples,
Hamburg lost one quarter of its population in 1565, Venice one third in
1575-1577, Naples nearly half in 1656. In London, some deaths were attributed
to the plague every year, and nine major episodes killed approximately 200,000
people between 1563 and 1665. Like all urban centers at the time, London had a
well-deserved reputation as an unhealthy place. Yet London kept growing
rapidly. Population pressure in the countryside continually pushed landless,
rootless, and adventurous migrants into the cities. In consequence, Europe was
considerably more urbanized in 1715 than in 1559.
By the late seventeenth century the plague
had nearly disappeared. Why this happened was not understood at the time, and is
still a subject of dispute by medical experts. The key may have been a
revolution among the rodents that infested all urban areas. The
long-established black rat, whose fleas transmit the plague bacillus to humans,
was ousted during the course of the century by the brown rat, whose fleas do
not spread the disease. At any rate, the last major plague epidemics in western
Europe took place in Marseilles in 1720 and in Messina in 1743.
Plague and famine acted as crude safety
valves to release excessive population pressure. In most regions of Europe,
inelastic production and rudimentary distribution made it impossible to feed or
employ the whole population when it rose above a certain ceiling. The western
and central regions could support much denser populations than the eastern or
northern regions, but nearly every state reached its tolerable maximum during
the late sixteenth century. In France this maximum seems to have been around
twenty million, in Italy around eleven million. Except in times of unusually bountiful
harvests, the French and Italians were certain to encounter subsistence crises
whenever their populations climbed far beyond these limits. Once the population
dropped, the high birthrate soon built it back up again. Just why the Spanish
experienced a net population loss in the seventeenth century, rather than the
kind of demographic oscillation found in France and Italy, is not clear. It
appears that the Spaniards so mismanaged their economic resources that
population density was forced downward. The German population pattern was also
exceptional. The Thirty Years’ War—with deaths resulting not only from combat
but from pestilence and from agricultural cutbacks, transportation breakdowns,
and consequent famine—had the demographic impact of the Black Death. But in
Germany, as in France and Italy, the high birthrate acted to restore population
losses; a strong demographic upswing occurred here after 1648.
In a few places there was net population
growth during the seventeenth century. It is not surprising that England’s
population increased, for density was not as great here as in sixteenth-century
France, Germany, or Italy, and the English had the resources to feed and employ
more people. The Dutch case is more instructive. The Dutch had no apparent room
for population growth, yet they did expand, supported by the highest per-
capita agricultural and industrial output and the most vigorous commercial
system in Europe. This development pointed the way to the future. Overall,
significant changes were beginning to take place that would make possible a new
demographic pattern. Though Europe’s total population was not growing in the
seventeenth century, productive capacity was certainly rising. A shrinking
farm population was raising enough food to sustain a rising urban population.
After 1715, the birthrate continued high, the plague ended, a long series of
good harvests ensued, and people were living longer; they had broken through
the seventeenth-century population ceiling. And in the late eighteenth century,
Europeans revolutionized their whole production system by introducing
scientific livestock breeding, soil chemistry, steam power, and manufacturing
by machine. In consequence, they could afford to abandon traditional
psychological restraints.
But during our period, people were closely
hemmed in by demographic restrictions. They had to accept extreme brevity of
life. One quarter of their newborn babies died within the first year. One half
died before reaching adulthood. Peasant couples in the region of Beauvais
produced five living children on average, yet the population level was only
barely sustained. The poets of the day feasted on the bittersweet theme of
brief young love, embellished by fading roses, drying dewdrops, and passing
spring. In the most popular English lyric of the seventeenth century, Robert
Herrick’s song “To the Virgins, to Make Much of Time,” the poet urges shy
maidens to:
Gather ye rosebuds while ye may,
Old Time is still a-flying;
And this same flower that smiles today,
Tomorrow will be dying.
In actual fact, the young people tended to
gather their rosebuds at a surprisingly slow pace. There is very little
evidence of bastardy or of premarital intercourse. The women in
seventeenth-century France and England married in their mid-twenties, the men
in their late twenties. When life was so short, why this delay in procreation
and marriage? Few young people had much practical choice. A couple could
scarcely marry until one or both drew a living wage, and most adolescents and
postadolescents in the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries labored for ten
years or more after puberty as dependent servants or apprentices, learning
their jobs but receiving little or no income. To understand why such a system
developed, we must look more closely into the economic and social structure of
early modern Europe.
AGRICULTURE AND INDUSTRY
Basic production methods remained
throughout our period much as they had been in 1500—indeed, as they had been in
1300. To be sure, the Dutch made some important changes in farming practices,
and the English developed some new techniques for heavy industry, but these
could not begin to compare with the innovations of the agricultural and
industrial revolutions of the eighteenth century. In the age of religious wars,
manufacture still retained its Latin meaning: “to make by hand.”
Economic enterprise was still shackled by manual labor.
It is not easy to generalize about
developments in agriculture. Broadly speaking, European food production became
more commercial and capitalistic between 1559 and 1715. Farmers grew cash
crops for the urban market on land they owned or rented. In western Europe,
landlords could make money in several ways. They might cultivate their estates
with wage labor, or lease out small plots to peasants, or take half of the
tenant’s crop in lieu of rent—this sharecropping system was called metayage
in France. Sharecropping was also common on the great Italian latifundia,
or estates, and on the latifundios of Spain. In Poland, Bohemia,
Hungary, and Prussia, landlords were less likely to bother with money wages or
rent; generally they required their serfs to farm their estates three days a
week without pay. The expanding agricultural market thus turned some western
European peasants into wage laborers, some into tenant farmers, and others into
small free farmers, while the eastern European peasants were driven deeper into
serfdom. Everywhere, the market economy was eroding traditional agrarian habits
of local self-sufficiency and cooperation within a close-knit community.
Many legacies from medieval agriculture
nevertheless remained. Villagers still divided their arable land into three
great fields to be planted with different crops in successive years. For
example, the English village of Wigston Magna was surrounded by three fields of
some nine hundred acres each, called Mucklow, Goldhill, and Thythorn Hill. In a
given year, Mucklow might be planted with peas and beans, and Goldhill with barley,
wheat, and rye, while Thythorn Hill was left fallow. These open fields were
subdivided into hundreds of individual holdings: narrow strips of land,
identifiable to their owners by the plow ridges along the edges. As in the
Middle Ages, each Wigston farmer held a number of these strips, but by the
seventeenth century some held many more than others. A half dozen entrepreneurs
had accumulated a hundred acres or more. The majority worked ten to thirty
acres, just enough to support a family. The poorest cottagers had no land and
hired out to their propertied neighbors. Yet these Wigston farmers, great and
small, still plowed and harvested in the communal rhythm of the open-field
system, as their forebears had been doing for a thousand years.
Wigston Magna’s time-honored but wasteful
three-field system of crop rotation prevailed through much of England, France,
and Germany. Plowing and harvesting techniques had not improved much since the
twelfth century. The yield per bushel of seed remained wretchedly low. The
traditional, undiversified crops were grown, mainly cereals and legumes, with little
in the way of meat, dairy produce, fruit, or leafy vegetables. The staples were
still bread and beer in the north, bread and wine in the south. Corn and
potatoes had been introduced from the New World, but were not yet widely
cultivated in Europe. Consumers were very grateful for the spices, sugar, tea,
and coffee which were imported from Asia and America.
It is interesting to compare conditions in
Spain, where agricultural production declined during the sixteenth and
seventeenth centuries, with conditions in England, where production increased.
In both Spain and England, large-scale wool raisers were converting grain
fields into sheep runs. In Spain, an estimated 3 per cent of the population
held 97 per cent of the land, so it was comparatively easy for the landlord
class to increase the percentage of land devoted to sheep pasturage. The
members of the Mesta, or sheep ranchers’ association, owned some three
million Merino sheep in the early sixteenth century. To graze this many
animals, a tremendous proportion of Castile’s barren land was required. The Spanish
government granted the Mesta special privileges; in 1501, their migratory
flocks were given exclusive possession of huge belts of pasture land which had
formerly been used to raise grain for the Castilian towns. In consequence, the
countryside was depopulated as the dispossessed fanners moved to the towns,
wheat production fell, and Spain was faced with famine. Ironically, in the
seventeenth century the Mesta flocks dwindled in size and value. During
the same period, aggressive English landlords evicted their tenants from a half
million acres of land and “enclosed” much of this land into great sheep
pastures. But the English enclosure movement did not assume major proportions
until the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries. In England the aristocracy and
gentry controlled less of the land than in Spain. At the close of the
seventeenth century, nearly half of the English rural population consisted of
small farmers who either owned their own land or held it on long leases. A more
important difference between England and Spain was that the English farmers,
large and small, worked their land more efficiently. Some enterprising farmers
created rich new farmland during the seventeenth century by draining the fen
district near Cambridge. Others cut down large forest tracts and learned how to
till areas which had hitherto been wasteland. Not only did wool production rise
in seventeenth-century England, but grain and cattle production more than kept
pace with the expanding population. By the close of the century, the English
farmers exported a good deal of wheat.
The Dutch were probably the most
enterprising agriculturists in Europe. They had to be, for they had very little
farmland on which to support a dense population. Their low-lying fields were
periodically inundated by the North Sea, and the soil was soggy. During the
sixteenth and seventeenth centuries, the Dutch reclaimed huge tracts, known as
polders, from the sea. They built dikes and drainage canals to keep the water
out, and windmills to pump the land dry. They farmed the new lands intensively,
planting orchards and truck gardens as well as grainfields and pasture. Raising
tulips—the colorful bulbs were introduced from Turkey in the sixteenth
century—became a Dutch specialty. They experimented with clover and turnips,
which improved the soil yield and fattened the cattle. The Dutch were able to
produce butter and cheese for export, whereas the English dairy farmers were
hampered by their practice of slaughtering most of their animals every fall for
lack of winter fodder. Spain, with its parched and rocky soil, badly needed
some Dutch-style agricultural experiments. But all efforts to irrigate the
Spanish fields were blocked by inertia. In the seventeenth century, Spanish
clerics rejected a canal project which was designed to improve inland
transport; if God had wanted Spain’s waterways to be navigable, they reasoned,
He would have made them so.
A good example of seventeenth-century
agrarian enterprise is the development by grape growers in the French county
of Champagne of a method for making superlative sparkling wine. French wines
were already well established as the best in Europe, but Champagne was not
among the great wine-producing regions. Its chalky soil grew stunted vines with
small quantities of particularly sweet white and black grapes. Its northerly
climate delayed the harvest season and slowed the crucial fermentation process
by which the grape juice was converted into alcohol. The standard method of
making wine was (and is) to harvest the grapes in September or October and
press them into a mush, which fermented. Before the fermented liquid turned
into vinegar, it was poured into great wooden casks. The liquid was then piped
from cask to cask in order to remove the sediment and filtered to achieve a
clear color. The standard seventeenth-century practice was to drink wine young,
but it could be casked for several years, until it matured into old wine. A blind
monk named Dom Pierre Perignon (1638-1715), the cellarer of a Benedictine
abbey, is supposed to have been the man who invented a new vintage process
which turned the still red wine of Champagne into a sparkling white wine.
First, Dom Pierre achieved a perfect blend by combining in the winepress
grapes from various different vines (he had a famous nose for the bouquet of
the grapes). Next, before the mush had completed its fermentation, Dom Pierre
poured the liquid into bottles instead of casks, and stored it in the cool
chalk cellars of Reims, the chief town in Champagne. The fermentation process
continued inside the bottles, giving the wine a bubbly effervescence. Dom
Pierre needed very strong bottles; in the early days of champagne making, a
great many of the bottles exploded. He needed strongly wired cork stoppers
instead of the oil-soaked wads of hemp which people had been using for bottle
stoppers. The development of a foolproof technique took many years. Since
bottled wine could not be piped or filtered, the producers of champagne had to
find another way of removing the sediment from their wine. They set the bottles
upside down in racks, and slightly twisted each bottle every day for many
months, until the sediment had settled on the cork. Then they had to open each
bottle, wipe off the sediment, hastily insert a pinch of sugar to give the wine
its sweet-dry flavor, and recork it before the effervescence was lost.
Seventeenth-century champagne may not have tasted very much like the modern
beverage, but it was already the toast of kings. Louis XIV drank it Copiously,
and Charles II was so pleased with the bubbly stuff when he visited France as a
young man that he introduced it into England.
Turning from food and drink to
manufacturing, we once again find regional divergences and a prevailing
tendency toward the large-scale capitalistic organization of production. In
the seventeenth century, industrial production was geared to elementary
consumer needs. Cloth is the most basic manufactured commodity, and in
seventeenth-century Europe, as in the Middle Ages, textile manufacturing was by
far the largest industry. Textile-production techniques had not changed since
the early sixteenth century. Utilitarian wool cloth, from which most garments
were made, was produced all over western Europe by the rural putting-out
system. Large- scale clothiers hired peasants to spin, weave, and finish their
cloth. Many clothiers did not attempt to dye the cloth, for dyeing required
skill; half the price of the finished cloth was in its color. Dutch clothiers
had the best formulas for wool dyeing (which they kept as secret as possible),
and they imported much “white” cloth from England and dyed it. The enterprising
clothier might buy raw wool from various strains of sheep, and experiment with
various mixtures and various weaves to get a cloth which struck the public’s
fancy. He might employ hundreds of men and women, and when he controlled every
stage by which the raw wool was converted into finished cloth, his organization
of production resembled that of the modern assembly-line factory. But the
actual work was performed under extremely primitive conditions, by semiskilled
hand labor.
Luxury fabrics, such as silk, were
produced in towns rather than in the countryside, because the work required a
delicate coalition between highly skilled laborers, costly materials, and
rather elaborate machinery. Only the rich could afford to buy silks and
velvets, and the silk merchant strove for quality rather than quantity. Lucca
had been the biggest Italian silk center since the thirteenth century; cities
farther north, such as Lyons and Amsterdam, developed the craft in the
sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. Naturally, the skilled silk weavers and
dyers of Lucca were better organized and better paid than the semiskilled wool
weavers and dyers of an English village. But they too were pieceworkers in a
large-scale enterprise.
The tailors who sewed the finished cloth
into garments were the most tradition bound of the textile workers. These
small, self-employed craftsmen were to be found in every European town. They
were organized, as they had been for centuries, into guilds. The tailor sewed
his garments according to prescribed guild standards and offered his wares to
the consumer at prescribed guild prices. The wool clothier and the silk
merchant abominated such protectionist, restrictive business procedures. Yet
the clothier himself expected the state to protect and promote all phases of
his textile production. The English government, like other governments,
obligingly prohibited English farmers from selling their wool abroad. It laid
heavy duties on all imported woolens. It bought domestic worsteds and serges
for military uniforms, and required that every English corpse be buried in a
woolen shroud. Actually, the seventeenth-century woolen industry had more in
common with the medieval tailoring craft than with the cotton industry which
was going to develop in England during the eighteenth century. Not only would
cotton be cheaper and more practical than wool, not only would cotton cloth be
made by machine rather than by hand, not only would cotton textile production
be concentrated in great factories rather than scattered in rural cottages, but
the cotton magnates would be so self-reliant that they could disdain all
regulation and protection, national as well as local. The textile manufacturers
of the seventeenth century, for all their aggressive organization, did not dare
to risk free competition. They thought they were living in a subsistence world.
There was not much spare capital or labor,
or much technical skill, for heavy industry. England was the most
industrialized society during the late sixteenth and seventeenth centuries. The
coal mines along the Tyne River in northern England were big affairs, with
elaborate machinery for draining the shafts, though not for cutting the coal.
The colliers mined and carted the coal by hand. English coal production
increased from approximately 200,000 tons a year in the 1550’s to 3,000,000
tons by the 1680’s. During the same span of years English iron production rose
fivefold. Because of these impressive gains, Professor John Nef, the chief
authority on the early British coal industry, argues that the English achieved
an “industrial revolution” between 1540 and 1640 comparable in importance to
the better-known machine age which began after 1760.4 But
“revolution” seems too strong a term for the industrial developments in Tudor
and Stuart England. The volume of seventeenth-century English coal and iron
output remained very modest, so modest that it could not greatly affect
techniques of production. The English did use coal fires in their dyehouses,
brick and glass kilns—and breweries, despite the cry that the smell of coke gas
tainted the beer. But they had not yet discovered how to smelt iron ore with
coal; this was still done by charcoal. Londoners consumed much of the new coal
in place of wood to heat their houses; the new iron supply was turned into
pots, grates, knives, pins, and other domestic articles. England in the 1640’s
produced 1/250 as much coal as the United States in the 1950’s, and 1/2500 as
much iron and steel. The English did not yet produce enough coal and iron to
substitute coal-powered, iron machinery for handicraft manufacturing—as they
would start doing in the cotton mills of the late eighteenth century.
Whether or not England experienced an
industrial revolution in the seventeenth century, continental Europe certainly
did not. The overall European output of iron and steel remained pretty steadily
at the low figure of 150,000 tons a year from the 1530’s into the early
eighteenth century. While English production was rising during these years,
iron and steel production in Germany, Bohemia, and Hungary was declining. War
is supposed to stimulate heavy industry, but the wars of religion probably had
the opposite effect. They disrupted mining and metalworking more than they
encouraged new enterprises. Weapons were still simple enough to be largely
handmade. The muskets and cannon which Gustavus Adolphus used in the Thirty
Years’ War were manufactured in Swedish state factories, but the gunpowder was
made in peasants’ cottages.
Transportation improved somewhat,
facilitating the distribution of market commodities from one European region
to another. Horse-drawn carriages and wagons were equipped for the first time
with spoked wheels and springs, which greatly eased overland travel and
transport. The pony-express postal couriers of the elector of Brandenburg
carried mail the six hundred miles from Konigsberg to Cleve in only a week. But
the narrow, rutted, muddy roads hindered the overland conveyance of bulk cargo,
as did the prevalence of highwaymen and toll collectors. It was calculated in
1675 that coal could be shipped three hundred miles by water as cheaply as
fifteen miles by road. Merchant ships were not much bigger or faster in 1715
than in 1559, but there were many more of them. The cheaply built, easily
handled Dutch flute, or flyboat, was particularly well designed for
carrying awkward cargoes like coal, timber, salt, or grain. Thus seaports and
riverports received goods from many parts of the world, while interior villages
still had to be nearly self-sufficient. The peasant who depended upon country
fairs and itinerant peddlars to supply his wants had to have modest tastes
indeed.
By and large, the seventeenth-century
economy suffered from chronic problems of underproduction, as our own economy
now suffers from chronic problems of overproduction. Almost the entire
seventeenth-century labor force was tied up in inefficient manual labor,
required to provide the bare necessities of life—food, clothing, shelter. Seven
or eight out of every ten members of the labor force were agricultural workers,
yet the people of seventeenth-century Europe were none too well fed or dressed.
Now, less than one out of ten members of the late twentieth-century American
labor force is an agricultural or textile worker, yet our farms and mills glut
the market. Of the 450 occupational categories listed by the United States
Bureau of the Census in 1970, at least two hundred (mostly of the white- collar
type) did not exist in any form three hundred years ago. A seventeenth-century
entrepreneur would hardly believe that in our mechanized society almost as many
laborers are engaged in transportation as in agriculture.5 Or that
we have to create consumer “wants” by sales and advertising, and persuade
customers to discard merchandise long before it wears out. The
seventeenth-century bourgeois virtues of thrift, abstinence, and restraint have
become vices in our era of built-in obsolescence.
DUTCH COMMERCIAL CAPITALISM
The Dutch were the most enterprising
businessmen in seventeenth-century Europe. Their success did not stem from
their superiority in agricultural and industrial production, though they were
indeed good farmers and skilled manufacturers. Primarily, they were middlemen:
they bought, sold, and carried other people’s products. They bought great quantities
of spices, tea, china, and cotton in Asia, and of sugar, tobacco, and furs in
America. They bought even greater quantities of lumber, grain, cattle, and
copper in northern Europe, and of wool, wine, silk, and silver in southern
Europe. With their ample fleet of merchant ships, the Dutch transported all
these commodities to Amsterdam and other Dutch towns, and sold them to the
buyers from all over Europe who congregated there. Whenever possible, they
enhanced their profits as middlemen by converting the raw materials they
imported into finished goods. The Dutch textile mills, dyehouses, breweries,
distilleries, tanneries, sugar and salt refineries, tobacco-cutting factories,
and soap works all depended on imported materials. By gearing their whole society
to foreign trade, the Dutch overcame their lack of natural resources, manpower,
and military strength. As Dutch prosperity proved, the merchant middleman was
the prime catalyst in the seventeenth-century economy.
The rise of Dutch commercial capitalism is
a remarkable story. When the Netherlander began their revolt against Philip II
in the 1560’s, the northern provinces (the future Dutch republic) were
decidedly less prosperous than the southern provinces. Amsterdam stood far
behind Antwerp as a commercial entrepot. But the inhabitants of Holland and
Zeeland, the two northern provinces bordering on the North Sea, had long been
seafaring folk and possessed many ships of all sizes. They already dominated
the North Sea fisheries and the Baltic grain and timber trade. Once the “sea
beggars” had captured ports in Holland and Zeeland in 1572, the Dutch could
ward off the Spanish army by opening the dikes when necessary; and they could
outsail the Spanish fleet and plunder the Spanish merchant marine. All through
the years between the Dutch declaration of independence in 1581 and the final
peace settlement with Spain in 1648, Dutch commerce boomed. Dutch merchants
aggressively developed old avenues of trade and opened new ones. Despite the
war, they kept on buying Spanish wool and selling grain to the Spaniards. They
even sold military stores to the Spanish army! They capitalized on Portugal’s
weakness during the Portuguese union with Spain (1580— 1640) by seizing the
most valuable Portuguese colonies and trading posts. When the duke of Parma
captured Antwerp in 1585, Amsterdam quickly replaced that city as Europe’s
greatest shipping center, commodity market, and financial exchange. The Dutch
insisted on blockading the mouth of the Scheldt River, Antwerp’s entrance to
the North Sea, to guarantee that Antwerp could never regain her old commercial
primacy.
The Dutch republic in the mid-seventeenth
century was very small, with an area about the size of the state of Maryland
and a population of two million. The eighty-year war with Spain had not caused
any appreciable modernization of its particularistic political structure. The
seven sovereign provinces—Holland, Zeeland, Utrecht, Gelderland, Groningen,
Overyssel, and Friesland—continued to cherish their separate identities. Cynics
called them the Disunited Provinces. Wealthy, crowded, cosmopolitan Holland had
few economic, social, or cultural bonds with backwater, feudal, cattle-raising
Gelderland. The central government, such as it was, functioned by means of
negotiations among the seven autonomous provinces. Each province sent
ambassadors to The Hague to meet in the States-General, a body which rarely
acted energetically because its decisions required the consent' of all seven
constituencies. But in a crisis the other six provinces deferred to Holland,
since the Hollanders contributed over half the union’s financial support.
Political control in Holland was vested in the merchant oligarchs who ruled
Amsterdam and the other towns. There was no central executive in the Dutch
republic, though William the Silent’s house of Orange developed some of the
attributes of a ruling dynasty. The prince of Orange was normally the commander
of the federal army and navy, and stadholder, or chief administrator, in
five of the seven provinces. The Dutch federation looked fragile and
impractical—but it worked. Dutch politics became a tug of war between the house
of Orange and the merchant oligarchs in Holland. Except in times of acute
military emergency, the merchant oligarchs prevailed. They wanted
international peace, which would facilitate the development of Dutch trade
throughout the world.
Seventeenth-century Dutch commercial
capitalism produced no individual titans to compare with Jacques Coeur, Cosimo
de Medici, or Jakob Fugger. Nevertheless, by pooling their resources the Dutch
merchants were able to undertake ventures which would have been too expensive
and risky for the solitary giants of the past. Great numbers of investors, big
and small, organized themselves into companies chartered by the state, in order
to tackle large commercial projects. The grandest of these companies, the Dutch
East India Company, was founded in 1602 with an initial capital of 6,500,000
florins. It was a joint-stock enterprise; hundreds of investors from all over
the Dutch republic pooled their money to give the company working capital. The
seventeen directors who operated the East India Company were drawn from among
the biggest shareholders, but the small shareholders had little to complain
about. The pepper, cloves, and nutmeg which the company brought to Amsterdam
netted an average annual dividend of 18 per cent.
By the mid-seventeenth century, the Dutch
had created a worldwide empire which differed in every way from the Spanish
empire. It was a trading network owned and operated by private enterprise,
with minimal government supervision. Two joint-stock companies, the East India
Company and the West India Company (founded in 1621), divided the globe between
them. Each of these companies had sovereign authority to possess and govern
overseas territory, to negotiate treaties, and to wage war. The East India
Company was the more important. In the early seventeenth century the company’s
soldiers and sailors drove the Portuguese out of the spice islands, the Malay
Archipelago, and Ceylon, and kept the English from moving into these places.
The Dutch thus secured virtually complete control over Sumatran pepper,
Ceylonese cinnamon, and Moluccan nutmeg, mace, and cloves. The company also
maintained a post on an island off Nagasaki, where the suspicious Japanese
government gave the Dutch a monopoly on all European trade with Japan. The
company shipped home tea and porcelain from its Chinese trading posts, cotton
from its Indian trading posts, silk from Persia, and coffee from Arabia. In
1652 the company established a way station at the Cape of Good Hope to break
the long sea voyage between Amsterdam and Asia. The Dutch West India Company,
operating in the western hemisphere, had less success because other European
states were too well entrenched there. It could not capture any major Spanish
colonies, and in the 1640’s and 1650’s the Portuguese reconquered Brazil and
Angola from the Dutch. In North America, the Dutch never got much profit out of
their fur-trading posts at Manhattan and Albany, and lost them to the English
in 1664. However, the West India Company did get good returns from the
lucrative African slave trade, and its island outposts of Curasao and St.
Eustatius proved to be useful bases for raiding and trading in the Caribbean.
The East India and West India companies
were dazzling symbols of Dutch commercial capitalism, but they were actually
less vital to the Dutch economy than the North Sea fishing industry and the
western European carrying trade. The fisheries employed several hundred
thousand Dutchmen. Many workers were needed to build, equip, and repair the
fishing smacks. Others manned the North Sea fleets which fished for herring,
haddock, and cod. Others manned the Arctic whaling fleets. Others pickled,
smoked, and barreled the catch for export. Still others fetched from Portugal
and France the salt needed to cure the herring, and from Norway the timber
needed in constructing the ships and the barrels. Despite the fact that they
had to import all their lumber, the Dutch built a great fleet of merchant
ships. Contemporaries guessed that the Dutch possessed sixteen thousand merchant
vessels in the mid-seventeenth century, something like half the European
total. Danish toll records indicate that two thirds of the ships which entered
the Baltic Sea during this period were Dutch. At times there were more Dutch
than Spanish ships off Spanish America, and more Dutch than English ships off
English America. In 1619, the first cargo of Negro slaves to Virginia was
carried in a Dutch ship. This carrying fleet enabled the Dutch to collect
middleman profits on nearly every branch of waterborne commerce, and caused
Amsterdam to develop into the busiest trading center in Europe.
During the century following the outbreak
of the Dutch revolt in 1566, the population of Amsterdam climbed from 30,000 to
200,000. The harbor was shallow and inconveniently inland from the North Sea,
but the city was the most northerly and the most defensible of the Dutch ports,
and was therefore safe from the Spanish. Amsterdam lay athwart the Baltic Sea,
Rhine River, and English Channel shipping routes. Nobody but nobody could
undersell the Amsterdam merchants because they dealt in volume. They would sail
a fleet of flyboats into the Baltic laden with herring (which Dutch fishermen
had caught off the English coast) and return with all of the grain surplus from
a Danish island, or with twenty thousand head of lean cattle to be fattened in
the Holland polders. They would buy a standing forest in Norway for timber, or
contract before the grapes were harvested for the vintage of a whole French
district. They would buy shiploads of undyed cloth, crude Barbados sugar, and
Virginia leaf in England; have the cloth dyed, the sugar refined, and the
tobacco cut and wrapped by Amsterdam craftsmen; and sell the finished
commodities all over northern Europe at prices the English could not match.
Foreign merchants found it worth their time to shop in Amsterdam because there
they could buy anything from a precision lens to muskets for an army of five
thousand. The exchange bank eased credit; marine insurance policies safeguarded
transport. And no merchant could feel a stranger in a city where the presses
printed books in every European tongue, and the French- and English-language
newspapers were more lively and informative than the gazettes printed back
home.
The Dutch republic was a Calvinist state,
but John Calvin would not have felt at home in mid-seventeenth-century
Amsterdam. The great Dutch merchants did not permit the Dutch Reformed clergy
to interfere in politics or business. Catholics, Anabaptists, Jews, and
unbelievers were tolerated in Amsterdam. The religious zeal which had stirred
the Dutch into rebellion against Philip II, and nerved them into continuing the
fight in the 1580’s when all seemed hopeless, had turned into a secular zeal
for making money. Indeed, the Dutch had lost more of their
mid-sixteenth-century crusading impetus than had their old adversaries, the
Spaniards. This loss of Dutch religious zeal is particularly evident if one
compares seventeenth-century Dutch and Spanish mission work among the heathen
overseas. Thousands of Spanish priests and monks proselytized vigorously in the
Philippines, India, Siam, and China, and maintained an elaborate network of
Catholic churches, schools, seminaries, and universities. The Dutch East India
Company sent a good many Calvinist ministers and schoolteachers into Asia, but
their missionary efforts were singularly feeble. “Nay,” lamented a Dutch
Calvinist in 1683, “while the Jesuits and other locusts of the whore of Babylon
apply so patiently their blind zeal to promote the Kingdom of Darkness, we do
so little to make the Kingdom of Mercy come!
The moneymaking ethos was certainly more
pervasive and powerful in Amsterdam than it had been in such earlier capitalist
centers as Florence, Venice, Augsburg, and Antwerp. We should not, however,
exaggerate the modernity of seventeenth-century Dutch commercial enterprise.
Amsterdam’s business structure—its bank, exchange, insurance companies, and
joint-stock companies—was based on sixteenth-century models. The characteristic
Amsterdam business firm continued to be a simple partnership. The Dutch
joint-stock companies resembled medieval guilds in their protectionist
policies. The East India Company had a monopoly 0n the eastern trade and forbade any Dutch
merchant not a shareholder from trading in the spice islands. The company did
more than just resist external competition; it deliberately destroyed some of
its own Sumatran pepper plantations and Molucca nutmeg cargoes in order to keep
the supply limited and the price high. Furthermore, Dutch commercial prosperity
was strictly limited to the upper and middle classes. The paintings of Jan
Vermeer and Pieter de Hooch, with their scenes of well-fed, well-dressed
burghers living in spotlessly clean, comfortably furnished brick houses,
illustrate only one side of seventeenth-century Dutch life. Half the
inhabitants of Amsterdam lived under slum conditions, in squalid shanties or
cellars. The Dutch wage laborer worked twelve to fourteen hours a day when he
was lucky enough to have a job and subsisted on a diet of beans, peas, and rye
bread. For all their enterprise, not even the Dutch could achieve an economy of
abundance in the seventeenth century.
PROPERTY AND PRIVILEGE
Europe’s relatively low productivity
during the sixteenth and seventeenth centuries helped keep its social structure
sharply stratified. Class lines were formalized to an extent hard for us to
credit. While there was more social mobility than in the Middle Ages, people
were no less self-conscious about their proper station in life. Every rank in
the social order, from princes and! , aristocrats at the top to serfs and
beggars at the bottom, had its own distinct style of dress, diet, habitation,
and entertainment; its own training, customs, and mental attitudes. The value
systems of the aristocrat, the bourgeois, and the peasant differed profoundly.
A person’s vocabulary and accent, even his physical posture, instantly
identified his social station, which helps explain why it was still exceptional
for anyone born into a given rank (especially at the bottom or top of the
scale) to climb up or down. Ilicr archy was considered a measure of
civilization. Social gradations might be rough and ready in frontier areas,
such as Ireland, Sweden, Russia, and America, but in France, the center of
civility, they were elaborated to the fullest extent. Ulysses’ oft-quoted
soliloquy in Shakespeare’s Troilus and Cressida perfectly expresses the
prevailing contemporary belief that social hierarchy preserves political order
and economic well-being.